Working Paper Series

No 106 / December 2019

Electoral cycles in macroprudential regulation

by

Karsten Müller

Abstract

Do politics matter for macroprudential policy? I show that changes to macropru- dential regulation exhibit a predictable electoral cycle in the run-up to 221 elections across 58 countries from 2000 through 2014. Policies restricting mortgages and consumer credit are systematically less likely to be tightened before elections during credit booms and economic expansions. Consistent with theories of opportunistic political cycles, this pattern is stronger when election outcomes are uncertain or in countries where political interference is more likely. In contrast to monetary policy, I find limited evidence that central banks are uniquely insulated from political cycles in macroprudential policy. These results suggest that political pressures may limit the ability of regulators to "lean against the wind."

JEL classifications: G18, G21, G28, D72, D73, P16

Keywords: Macroprudential regulation, electoral cycles, regulatory cycles, political economy, central bank independence

1

  • Introduction

In the wake of the Great Financial Crisis of 2008-2009, many countries have made sweeping changes to financial regulation. Because banking crises tend to follow periods of high growth in credit1, there has been widespread agreement in policy and academic circles that macroprudential regulation can help to mitigate risks to the financial sector as a whole (IMF, 2017; Aikman, Haldane & Nelson, 2015). As a consequence, such macropru- dential tools have become part of the standard macroeconomic policy toolkit around the globe (Cerutti, Claessens & Laeven, 2015).

A growing theoretical literature suggests that restricting excessive leverage, especially in the household sector, could be welfare-improving.2 Recent empirical work has found that macroprudential tools can stabilize growth in credit and house prices (e.g. BIS, 2017).3 However, existing work is silent on potential political challenges to implementing macroprudential policies. Because these policies restrict voters' access to credit and also have immediate eects on financial institutions, politicians may have considerable incentives to interfere with their implementation (e.g. Haldane, 2017).

In this paper, I investigate empirically whether politics matter for changes to macro- prudential policy across countries. Anecdotal evidence abounds: in Ireland, for example, the incumbent government pledged to reduce stamp duties for first-time homebuyers in the run-up to the 2007 general election at the height of the 2000s housing boom (Irish Times, 2007).4 I show that such case studies are part of a systematic pattern. Using quar-

  • See, for example, Kindleberger (1978), Gourinchas & Obstfeld (2012), and Schularick & Taylor (2012).

2Much of this literature studies macroprudential policies in the presence of pecuniary externalities and incomplete markets (e.g. Lorenzoni, 2008; Bianchi, 2011; Korinek & Simsek, 2016; Jeanne & Korinek, 2018; Bianchi & Mendoza, 2018). Another strand also incorporates nominal rigidities (e.g. Schmitt-Grohé & Uribe, 2016; Farhi & Werning, 2016).

  • See, among others, Jiménez, Ongena, Peydró & Saurina (2017), Aiyar, Calomiris & Wieladek (2016), Aiyar,
    Calomiris & Wieladek (2014), Gambacorta & Murcia (2017), Ayyagari, Beck & Peria (2017), and Epure, Mihai, Minoiu & Peydró (2017), who show that prudential policies aect loan and firm-level outcomes. Al- tunbas, Binici & Gambacorta (2018) show that macroprudential policy aects bank risk. Macroeconomic evidence includes IMF (2011), Kuttner & Shim (2016), and Akinci & Olmstead-Rumsey (2015).
  • In the United States, the economic expansion under President Trump has been accompanied by a removal of qualitative grades for American banks' stress tests, an increase in the size thresholds for systematically
    important banks six months before the 2018 midterm elections, and a widely noted decision not to raise countercyclical capital buers (Financial Times, 2019). In Germany, parliament blocked the introduction of income-based lending limits for households eight weeks before the 2017 election (German Council of Economic Experts, 2017).

2

terly data on 58 countries between 2000 to 2014, I find that targeted macroprudential policy is predictably looser in the run-upto general elections. This finding is robust to controlling for a large number of macroeconomic and financial sector variables, using a wide array of model specifications and estimation techniques, and including a stringent set of country year fixed eects, which means comparing the quarters around elections in the same country in the same year. A battery of tests suggest that upcoming elections, not dierences in fundamentals, likely explain these patterns.5

Macroprudential policy is particularly looser in the run-up to elections with uncertain outcomes, where the stakes for incumbents are the highest. This cycle is also stronger for regular elections, i.e. those held in the quarters determined by a country's constitution or common practice, which may give incumbents more time to interfere (see Nordhaus, 1975; Ito, 1990; Alesina, Cohen & Roubini, 1992). This also suggests that upcoming elections are unlikely to be the result rather than the cause of changes in regulation.

The election cycle in macroprudential policy reflects a lack of tightening targeted sectoral tools during "good times", rather than an active loosening of regulation. Policy makers are less likely to tighten regulations before elections during economic expansions and financial sector booms when credit growth and bank profitability are high. This may not be coincidental: because contractions in credit markets are politically costly (Funke, Schularick & Trebesch, 2016; Antoniades & Calomiris, 2018; Doerr, Gissler, Peydro & Voth, 2018; Gyongyosi & Verner, 2019), politicians have strong incentives to urge regulators not to choke o economic expansions before elections (e.g. Gersbach & Rochet, 2014). Of course, boom times are precisely when countercyclical macroprudential policy is supposed to help cushion bank balance sheets against a reversal of fortunes. As such, one interpretation is that the electoral cycle weakens eorts to decrease the financial sec- tor's procyclicality. While only suggestive, I also do not find that regulatory decisions are merely postponed until after the election. Taken at face value, this means electoral cycles could lead to permanently looser policy.

I construct cross-sectional tests to study the potential mechanisms underlying looser macroprudential regulation before elections. The evidence is broadly consistent with

5The large literature on political business cycles suggests that, if anything, potentially unobserved monetary and fiscal policies should be looser before elections (e.g. Shi & Svensson, 2006). This works against finding an electoral cycle in macroprudential regulation because, if other policies are loose, one would expect countercyclical financial regulation to be more, not less stringent.

3

models of opportunistic political cycles, where incumbent governments try to signal competency with economic fundamentals (e.g. Rogo & Sibert, 1988; Rogo, 1990). As a first indication, the electoral cycle is strongest for the sectoral tools that target mortgage and consumer credit - arguably the policies that most directly aect the median voter. I find less evidence for broader instruments. The cycle is also particularly pronounced in countries with weaker political institutions, higher state intervention, more political linkages between regulators and politicians, and a weak opposition. Taken together, these results point in the direction of political interference aimed at voters.

I find no evidence for a role of special interests and regulatory capture in explaining the electoral cycle. Voters, not banks, seem to be the reason for looser targeted macro- prudential policy around elections. I also find no evidence that uncertainty about future governments' economic policies gives rise to a "wait and see" cycle in macroprudential tools. This could be the case if regulators observe higher uncertainty about firm investments in the run-up to elections and thus forego tightening policy. However, I find no evidence that electoral cycles vary with proxies for uncertainty about economic policy.

A key question these patterns raise is whether institutional frameworks matter for electoral pressures in the use of macroprudential tools. In the case of monetary policy, central bank independence is often thought of as a backstop for political interference (Cukierman, 1992; Eijnger & de Haan, 1996; Crowe & Meade, 2007). A widespread assumption seems to be that independent central banks also anchor macroprudential tools (see e.g. Viñals, 2013). To my knowledge, however, we do not have empirical evidence whether this is indeed the case.

Several factors suggest that targeted macroprudential policies may be quite dierent from monetary policy. First, targeted credit policies have more immediate distributional and thus politically sensitive eects than changes in monetary policy (Kane, 1977; Agur & Sharma, 2013; Fischer, 2014; Tucker, 2016). Second, the eects of macroprudential tools on borrowers can be more easily counteracted by fiscal authorities, e.g. through the use of taxes or subsidies for housing. Indeed, some policy makers argue that coordination with governments is desirable to undo potential unintended harm of these tools (e.g. Fischer, 2014, 2015). This also means independence may be less useful than for monetary policy. Third, "financial stability" as a policy target is vaguely defined and the policy levers are less well understood than for monetary policy. This may also lead to an unwillingness to

4

tighten policy before elections.6

In the data, I find limited evidence that central banks are uniquely isolated from the electoral cycle in macroprudential tools. Central bank independence does not seem to be key for mitigating electoral pressures, both where central banks control macroprudential policy decisions and where they do not. In contrast, central bank independence matters consistently for electoral cycles in monetary policy, in line with previous evidence (see e.g. Havrilesky, 1988; Cukierman, 1992; Abrams, 2006; Alpanda & Honig, 2009; Dubois, 2016). While countries with low central bank independence show signs of lower policy rates and higher growth in central bank reserves before elections, this pattern disappears for countries with highly independent monetary authorities. Taken together, this suggests that targeted tools may create incentives for politicians to interfere with macroprudential policy, even where central bank independence appears to insulate monetary policy. I also find some evidence that electoral cycles are less of a concern in countries where financial stability committees decide on regulation.

To the best of my knowledge, this paper is the first to systematically investigate the politics of macroprudential regulation. I build on three broad strands of the literature. First, my work is grounded in work on opportunistic political cycles (see e.g. Drazen (2000) and Dubois (2016) for surveys). There is considerable evidence that incumbent governments benefit from favorable economic performance and thus have incentives to manipulate policies before elections (see e.g. Nordhaus, 1975; MacRae, 1977; Tufte, 1978; Keech, 1995).7 Brown & Dinc (2005), Dam & Koetter (2012), and Behn, Haselmann, Kick

  • Vig (2015) show that bank bail-outs are less likely to happen before elections in a vari- ety of settings. Drawing on a plethora of case studies, Dagher (2017) argues that regula- tory easing in the run-up to banking crises seems to be the rule rather than the exception. Herrera, Ordoñez & Trebesch (2014) show that increases in government popularity pre- dict financial crises, over and above financial and macroeconomic variables; my results mesh well with their finding that these pre-crisis increases in popularity coincide with financial deregulation.

6Many case studies of political interference in financial regulation are countries with arguably excellent institutions, such as the United States or the United Kingdom (e.g. Calomiris & Haber, 2014).

7There is evidence for political cycles in, among others, fiscal transfers (e.g. Akhmedov & Zhuravskaya, 2004), local tax rates (e.g. Foremny & Riedel, 2014; Alesina & Paradisi, 2017), and monetary policy (e.g. Alesina et al., 1992; Block, 2002; Clark & Hallerberg, 2000).

5

Second, my paper is related to the literature on political interference in (government) bank lending. Previous work by Sapienza (2004), Khwaja & Mian (2005), Dinc (2005), Cole (2009), Carvalho (2014), Halling, Pichler & Stomper (2016), Haselmann, Schoen- herr & Vig (2018), Englmaier & Stowasser (2017), and Koetter & Popov (2019) suggests that government ownership of banks is associated with political lending, particularly during election periods. Akey, Dobridge, Heimer & Lewellen (2018) and Akey, Heimer & Lewellen (2018) show that politicians actively use their influence over lenders to reallocate credit in their interest. I also study political interference in credit markets but with a focus on regulatory actions.

Third, my paper is related to the broader literature on the political economy of finance (e.g. Kroszner & Strahan, 1999; Rajan & Zingales, 2003; Braun & Raddatz, 2008; Benm- elech & Moskowitz, 2010; Calomiris & Haber, 2014). Perhaps most related is work by Gyongyosi & Verner (2019), Doerr et al. (2018), and Funke et al. (2016), who show that disruptions in credit markets can lead voters to shun incumbent governments and vote for extremist parties. Antoniades & Calomiris (2018) provide evidence that voters punish incumbents in US presidential elections if they are cut o from mortgage credit. Mian, Sufi & Trebbi (2010) and Mian, Sufi & Trebbi (2013) study how special interests shape legislative decisions in financial regulation; Chavaz & Rose (2018) and Bertrand, Kra- marz, Schoar & Thesmar (2018) show that firms, in turn, may help or reward politicians. Johnson & Mitton (2003) show that imposing capital controls in Malaysia in 1998 primarily benefited firms connected to the prime minister; Igan, Lambert, Wagner & Zhang (2017) study how lobbying aects the sale of failed banks in the US. I add to this body of work by providing evidence that macroprudential regulations - widely hoped to prevent future financial crises - may be subject to political limitations.

  • Data and Econometric Framework

2.1 Data

I combine four dierent types of data for the empirical analysis: (1) data on changes in macroprudential policy; (2) data on general election dates; (3) data on macroeconomic and financial sector conditions; and (4) data on a wide range of institutional and political characteristics. I briefly discuss each and refer the interested reader to the online

6

appendix. Tables 1 and A1 provide summary statistics; tables A2, A3, and A4 outline details on variable construction and sources.

Data on macroprudential policy changes For my baseline results, I use the cross-country database on prudential policy instruments compiled by Cerutti, Correa, Fiorentino & Segalla (2017). This dataset comprises quarterly data on changes in the intensity of regulatory tools for 64 countries from the first quarter of 2000 to the fourth quarter of 2014. The data dierentiate between capital buers (general or sector-specific), limits to in- terbank exposures, concentration limits, loan-to-value (LTV) ratios, and reserve require- ments. Because the data on LTV ratios are barely filled, I add the data on changes in LTV limits from Kuttner & Shim (2016).8 The data include two aggregate indices: one tracks changes in any instrument (ranging from -1 to 1) and the other changes in sectoral capital requirements (ranging from -3 to 3). Sectoral capital requirements are regulations aimed at real estate credit, consumer credit, or other sectors. In practice, many of these reflect changes to risk weights on particular loan types, e.g. on mortgages. For more information on sources and variable construction, I refer the interested reader to Cerutti et al. (2017).

The use of macroprudential tools between 2000 and 2014 is widely dispersed across countries and time. The countries with the most changes in any macroprudential tool are Serbia and India (26 changes), followed by Brazil (24 changes) and Argentina (22 changes). Sector-specific capital buers are most frequently used in Brazil (9 changes), India (8 changes), followed by Thailand and Israel (4 changes). Overall, I observe the most policy changes in Eastern and Northern Europe (93 and 75 changes, respectively) as well as South America (83 changes). Sectoral capital buers are also most popular in Europe (20 changes) and South America (13 changes).9 There is considerable individual variation in the use of macroprudential tools, as suggested by the relatively low correlations among regulatory changes (ranging from -0.05 to 0.21).10

Throughout the paper, I focus on sectoral capital buers as my baseline measure of macroprudential policy stance. These tools are widely used and highly targeted towards real estate and consumer credit, which likely makes them particularly prone to political

8Note that the datasets do not follow comparable classifications for other regulatory changes, so I do not merge data on other tools. I discuss this issue in more detail in section 3.7.

  • I plot the number of changes by year and country in figure A1 in the online appendix.

10The correlations between the individual measures can be found in the online appendix Table A5.

7

interference.11 I will also consider how other tools vary with the timing of elections.

I also replicate my main results using data on macroprudential policy changes from Kuttner & Shim (2016) and Budnik & Kleibl (2018), who cover fewer countries and/or policy tools. I discuss the construction of these variables in the online appendix. As I discuss in section 3.7, the correlation of changes in macroprudential tools across sources is surprisingly low. I thus chose not to aggregate the data across sources.

Data on general elections I merge the data on changes in macroprudential regulation with election dates in 58 democratic countries. Electoral cycle theories posit that politicians may attempt to influence policy to target special interest groups or the median voter. As such, identifying such cycles requires countries with reasonably credible elections. I thus only keep countries that have a score above 0 on the Polity IV scale in all sample years from 2000 through 2014, as in Canes-Wrone & Ponce de Leon (2018) (also see Pers- son & Tabellini, 2003; Epstein, Bates, Goldstone, Kristensen & O'Halloran, 2006). This requirement eliminates China, Hong Kong, Kuwait, Saudi Arabia, and Vietnam from the dataset on prudential regulation. I also drop Luxembourg, where - given its role as a tiny financial center country - macroprudential regulation may not predominantly target the domestic economy. In section 3.5, I show that the sample selection makes no dierence to my results.

To identify elections, I start with the Polity IV database, the Database of Political Institutions (Beck, Clarke, Gro & Keefer, 2001), updated by Cruz, Keefer & Scartascini (2018), the Comparative Political Data Set (Armingeon, Wenger, Wiedemeier, Isler, Knöpfel, Weisstanner & Engler, 2017), and the Global Elections Database (Brancati, 2017). These datasets list the months and years of elections around the world. I first identify each country's most relevant elections based on the selection of chief executives. In presidential systems such as the United States, power is normally concentrated in the oce of the president. In parliamentary systems such as Germany's, prime ministers or premiers are the relevant figures, who are elected in parliamentary elections. Since the classification is unclear in a few cases, I hand-check all elections by drawing on additional information from various internet resources. I also cross-check my classification with Julio & Yook (2012). Table A6 in the appendix plots the total number of tightening and loosening

11I do not take a stand on whether politicians, bankers or voters understand the exact nature of these tools. What matters in my setting is whether they are seen as potentially restricting credit.

8

episodes for each macroprudential tool by election quarter. Table A7 details the number of tightening and loosening episodes across countries, the number of elections, and the type of elections used. Table A8 in the online appendix provides a list of the elections.

Theory predicts that political cycles should be stronger when incumbent governments are uncertain about electoral outcomes. I thus also dierentiate elections by whether their outcome is ex-ante hard to predict. Because I do not have reliable polling data for a suf- ficient fraction of elections, I follow the existing literature and use actual election results as a proxy (see e.g. Julio & Yook, 2012; Canes-Wrone & Park, 2012; Canes-Wrone & Ponce de Leon, 2018). I define relatively close elections as those in which the winner achieves a margin of victory below the median; for presidential systems, I interpret results that are below the median in the last-round presidential vote share as relatively more com- petitive. I also single out "regular" elections, which are defined as those that are held within a country's institutionally determined time frame or common practice.12 Half of the elections in my sample are close and around three quarters are regular.

Data on macroeconomic and financial sector conditions Changes in regulation likely depend on the state of the economy, particularly the financial sector. I control for key quarterly macroeconomic variables using data from the International Monetary Fund's International Financial Statistics, the OECD, and annual financial sector data from the World Bank's Global Financial Development Database. For Argentina, I add data from the Instituto Nacional de Estadística y Censos (INDEC). Data on uncertainty come from Baker, Bloom & Davis (2016) and Ahir, Bloom & Furceri (2018).

Data on institutional and political characteristics I obtain data on central bank independence from Crowe & Meade (2007), Dincer & Eichengreen (2014), and Garriga (2016). Data on macroprudential institutions is from Edge & Liang (2017) and Cerutti et al. (2015). I construct a variety of political characteristics based on data from the World Governance Indicators, Freedom House, Polity IV, and a few other sources. I also construct a new indicator of whether a central bank's governor has previous work experience in a country's Ministry of Finance or private financial sector, extending an existing dataset from Mishra & Reshef (2019). See online appendix Table A2 for more details.

12I allow one quarter deviation from the exact quarter of the previous election, similar to Julio & Yook (2012), which is unlikely to reflect severe meddling with election timing.

9

2.2 Econometric Framework

The backbone of my empirical analysis are fixed eects dynamic panel regressions of the following type, as standard in the election cycle literature:

Rit = i + t + P re electionit + X0+ (L)Rit1 + "it;

(1)

where i and t index countries and year-quarters, respectively. i and t refer to a full set of fixed eects. I also consider specifications with country year fixed eects. In most cases, R will refer to changes in sectoral capital buers. These tools mostly target mortgage and consumer credit, which makes them particularly prone to political interference.

The main variable of interest is a dummy for the pre-election period P re electionit that takes the value of 1 in the quarter before an election takes place, following the standard approach in previous studies using quarterly data (see e.g. Schultz, 1995; Canes- Wrone & Park, 2012; Julio & Yook, 2012). In section 3.1, I explore how regulation changes from one year before to one year after elections and find that the average eects are most pronounced for pre-election quarters.13 In principle, election timing may also be aected by changes in financial regulation; I address this in section 3.1 by splitting elections into whether they are "regular" and thus pre-determined, i.e. held within the limit implied by a country's constitution or regular practice.

X0 is a vector of variables that describe the state of the economy and financial sector. For the baseline set of controls, I use eleven lagged quarterly macro and seven annual financial sector variables.14 (L)Rit1 is a vector of lags of the dependent variable to account for autocorrelation in regulatory decisions; in the main regressions, I set the lag polynomial (L) to 1.15 Note that the results appear to be unaected by "Nickell bias":

13This timing is broadly consistent with research on the eectiveness of macroprudential policies, which suggests that these aect the macroeconomy with a lag of about one quarter (e.g. BIS, 2017). However, I show below that regulation is already looser up to a three quarters before elections during credit booms or economic expansions.

14These include government spending/GDP, the money market interest rate, growth of central bank re- serves, real credit growth, real GDP growth, current account/GDP, total trade/GDP, investment/GDP, private consumption/GDP, CPI growth, the nominal USD exchange rate, bank capitalization, a measure of banking sector concentration, banks' cost-to-income ratio, the NPL ratio, bank return on assets, bank Z-score, and the share of foreign banks. See the online appendix for more details.

15Lag selection tests using the Bayesian or Akaike information criteria suggest autocorrelation of between

10

they also hold using specifications without lagged dependent variable or estimation using panel GMM (see section 3.5). "it is an error term that is assumed to be well behaved. Standard errors are clustered by country.

I estimate the baseline regressions using ordinary least squares (OLS). In some speci- fications, I transform the dependent variables into dummies for a tightening or loosening of macroprudential policy. In principle, these regressions could also be estimated using maximum likelihood estimators. However, this is not feasible for many specifications because of the combination of two-way fixed eects, interaction terms, and completely separated variables.16 In section 3.5, I replicate all regressions with dummy dependent variables using logistic regressions as well as a bias-corrected logit estimator for two-way fixed eects (Fernández-Val & Weidner, 2016).

2.3 Are Pre-Election Quarters Different?

A potential challenge for identifying electoral cycles in regulation is that macroeconomic and financial sector variables may themselves be subject to an electoral cycle. If, for example, financial conditions before elections are relatively gloomy, regulators may see less reason to interfere or loosen existing measures. In the data, we may thus observe a negative correlation of P re electionit and Rit even in the absence of a causal eect of upcoming elections on regulation.

Whether observable fundamentals are dierent in the run-up to elections is an empirical question. I put this to a first test in Table 2, where I run panel regressions of the type in equation 1 but replace the dependent variable with one of the control variables. I allow for two specifications. In the first, P re electionit refers to the quarter immediately before an election. In the second, I include dummies for each of the four quarters before elections and plot the linear combination of the estimated coecients.

I find no evidence for large, systematic observable dierences in financial and macroeconomic conditions between the election and non-election periods across countries. This

zero and eight quarters. I use one lag as a baseline. As I show in section 3.5, the exact number of lags makes virtually no dierence to the results.

16Complete separation of a variable arises when a variable perfectly predicts an outcome. This is the case in my setting because, for example, out of the 51 changes in sector-specific capital requirements in the sample, none occur in pre-election quarters. Models with completely separated variables cannot be estimated using maximum likelihood because the likelihood of no change in sector-specific capital requirements in pre-election quarters is infinity by definition.

11

is true both for the levels of these variables and their first dierences, which could pick up high-frequency movements rather than deviations from country means.17 A simple t- test for the equality of means before elections (relative to all other periods) yields almost equivalent results.18 For the majority of variables, the t-statistics are clearly below one. Even for the more precise estimates, the coecients switch signs between specifications. This non-finding is not entirely surprising: the existing literature on political business cycles has found mixed and largely context-dependent evidence for electoral cycles in macroeconomic outcomes (see e.g. Drazen, 2000; Dubois, 2016).

Apart from the suggestive evidence above, theories of political business cycles predict that other policies should be expansionary before elections. If anything, this means that regulators should pursue tighter, not looser regulation in pre-election quarters. To interpret the estimates from equation 1 as the eect of elections on macroprudential tools, I thus have to assume that unobserved time-varying country factors that are suciently orthogonal to the control variables are not the sole cause of dierences in macroprudential regulation around elections. I argue that this assumption is likely to hold.

As we will see momentarily, my finding of looser regulation before elections also holds after including a large number of controls. To abstract from the most obvious confounders, I also allow for a specification of equation 1 that includes country year fixed eects. This means comparing the quarters around elections in the same country in the same year. It also eases the identifying assumption one has to make to believe that changes in macroprudential policy are influenced by upcoming elections.

  • Results

3.1 Baseline Results

To begin, figure 1 plots the average change in the sectoral capital buers and the overall macroprudential regulation indices for pre-election and all other quarters. For sector- specific tools, the magnitudes go in opposite directions: regulation is loosened before elections and tightened in all other periods in the sample. The bar chart on the right suggests that regulation is, on average, tightened in every quarter, but less so in pre-

17The latter results can be found in Table A11 in the online appendix. 18These results are plotted in Table A12 in the online appendix.

12

election quarters.

I next challenge these correlations to a regression-based test based on running equation 1. Table 3 shows the main results. I begin by looking at the index of changes in sector-specific capital requirements that particularly target real estate and consumer credit. These tools are widely used, are likely to immediately aect the median voter, and also exhibit the strongest electoral cycle. I then turn to the results for individual tools and provide graphical evidence.

In column 1, I begin by running a fixed eects panel regression without controls. The coecient of 0:020 is statistically significant at the 5% level. It is also remarkably large: since the mean change of sector-specific capital buers is 0:011, the eect of pre-election periods is large enough to explain why regulations loosen at these times compared to the rest of the sample quarters. Given that the standard deviation of the dependent variable is 0:182, this implies electoral cycles explain around 11% of the variation in macropru- dential policy decisions. Next, I introduce the vector of macroeconomic and financial sector control variables to absorb dierences in observable fundamentals in column 2. Using the relatively large number of controls reduces the number of observations; the point estimate, however, increases to 0:029 and is still precisely estimated. This model specification will serve as the baseline model for most of the paper. In column 3, I add country year eects, which eectively means comparing the electoral cycle within the same country in the same year. This yields an even larger coecient of 0:041 (signifi- cant at the 1% level).19 It implies that more than 20% of the variation in sectoral capital buers is driven by pre-election periods. Column 4 uses an alternative approach and absorbs countryelection year dummies, thereby removing any average dierences between years with and without elections. The coecient of 0:039 is highly similar and also sig- nificant at the 5% level. As I will show below, the fact that conditioning on these full sets of interacted dummies does little to the point estimate is because most of the average eect on regulation is concentrated in the quarters immediately before an election.

Could it be that I am not suciently conditioning on past fundamentals, such as the path of monetary and fiscal policy? In column 5, I add four quarters of lags of each vari- able. The point estimate and its statistical precision remain unaected, despite including

19Note that the observation count of this specification is slightly higher than that in column 2 because the interacted fixed eects do not require countries to have data on the annual financial sector controls.

13

an additional 51 covariates. As a last check, I further add a lead of each of the control variables. The idea is that, while I do not have data on forecasts for each variable, future realizations may serve as a proxy for expected changes in these fundamentals. Again, this leaves the point estimate largely unchanged at 0:029 and still significant at the 5% level.

The fact that the coecient for pre-election periods is almost unchanged across specifi- cations suggests that dierences in economic or financial conditions are unlikely to drive the regulatory easing I observe.

Figure 2 graphically plots changes in sectoral capital buers around elections. More precisely, I rerun the baseline regression equation 1 but replace the pre-election dummy with dummies for the election quarter and four leads and lags of it. I continue to control for country and year-quarter fixed eects, as well as the control variables. The pre- election quarter stands out in terms of magnitude and statistical significance: on average, the cycle seems to be concentrated immediately before elections, consistent with the literature on political business cycles (e.g. Akhmedov & Zhuravskaya, 2004). As we will see later, regulation is already lower up to three quarters before elections during credit booms. There also seems to be a minor re-balancing in the post-election period, but this is far from statistically significant. I will return to a more formal test of post-election reversals in section 3.4.

I next dierentiate between tightening and loosening episodes for individual macro- prudential instruments in Table 4. The dependent variable is now a dummy equal to 1 for a tightening or loosening, and 0 otherwise. I consider specifications with and without controls and dierentiate tools by whether they target particular sectors or not.20 I classify changes in general capital requirements and reserve requirements for local currency assets as broader tools, which are mostly intended to aect bank health and total credit.

My findings suggest that electoral cycles in prudential regulation are particularly pronounced for targeted sectoral tools. Crucially, targeted tools have also been found to be among the most eective in curbing credit and house price growth (e.g. Akinci & Olmstead-Rumsey, 2015). What particularly stands out is the highly significantly lower likelihood of tightening before elections for tools aimed at housing and consumer lend- ing. Similar to the patterns in the raw data, the implied eect sizes are large: after con-

20Table 1 in the appendix plots full descriptive statistics including observation counts. I consider nonlinear estimators in the robustness section below.

14

trolling for fundamentals in column 2, pre-election periods explain 15% of the standard deviation in capital buers aimed at residential mortgages. LTV ratio limits are also less likely to be tightened before elections.21 I find some less robust results for inter- bank exposures and concentration limits, which are also targeted tools. The evidence is much more limited for local currency reserve requirements or general capital require- ments, which do not target particular sectors.22

How should we interpret these results? The first takeaway is that there is a strong nonlinearity in the political cyclicality of macroprudential regulation. Regulators seem to forego tightening rather than actively loosen policy before elections. Second, and perhaps more importantly, sectoral tools aimed at mortgages and consumer loans appear to react especially strongly to upcoming elections.

3.2 The Role of Close and Regular Elections

Next, I investigate dierences in election timing and competitiveness in Table 5. Column 1 reproduces the baseline specification (as in column 2 in Table 3). In column 2, I consider only pre-election quarters of "regular" elections, defined as those held within the time frame specified in a country's constitution or established as regular practice. To illustrate with two well-known recent examples: the 2017 election in the United Kingdom (announced only two months in advance) would be considered irregular; the 2016 presidential election in the United States (four years after the previous one) would be considered regular. Three-quarters of the elections in my sample are regular.

I find considerably larger eects in the run-up to regular compared irregular elections. The pre-election dummy has a coecient of 0:035 for regular compared to 0:014 for irregular elections (the latter is statistically insignificant). The advantage of only coding regular pre-election quarters as 1 is that they are by definition not the outcome of economic fundamentals. Endogeneous election timing thus does not seem to be a major factor in my setting. The result of a larger electoral cycle for regular elections is also intuitive from a political economy angle: incumbent politicians may be able to influence policy more when they have a longer time horizon to interfere, as is the case when election

21Note that, for the LTV ratio changes, the pre-election dummy refers to the second quarter prior to an election, where the eects seem to be largest.

22I also do not find average eects for earlier quarters before elections.

15

timing is predictable (Nordhaus, 1975).

In columns 4 and 5, I split the sample by whether the pre-election dummy precedes election outcomes that are more or less likely to be predictable ex-ante. More precisely, I dierentiate between election outcomes that are relatively "close" in terms of the winner's margin of victory. The point estimate for close elections in column 4 now jumps to 0:053 (statistically significant at the 5% level). The estimate for elections with a more certain outcome is considerably smaller at 0:005 and statistically insignificant. This suggests that the electoral cycle in sectoral capital buers is concentrated in periods when incumbents face uncertainty about election outcomes - and may thus have more incentive to interfere with regulation.

Figure 5 plots these dierences across types of elections visually. More precisely, I plot the estimated coecients for the pre-election dummy and the associated 95% confidence intervals. This underscores that the political cycle in macroprudential policy is driven by those elections where incumbents have both the largest incentive and ability to interfere.

3.3 Electoral Cycles and Procyclical Regulation

Whether election cycles in macroprudential regulation pose a potential challenge to the design of regulatory frameworks depends on when they occur. By design, these tools are supposed to be countercyclical. They should be tightened during credit expansions that may be accompanied by increased risk taking. This means electoral cycles are potentially more damaging if they occur during booms, and thus partly undermine (or even reverse) countercyclical policies.

The experience of senior policy makers suggests that political pressures may be particularly strong during booms. Kohn (2014), for example, argues: "Highlighting the cyclical risk and recommending raising capital or liquidity requirements in good times are not going to win any political popularity contests. Banks and other lenders will deny the risk, and will point to the fact that they are already well-capitalized and enjoying good profits. Households and businesses will be resistant to higher costs or nonprice constraints on borrowing as they seek to finance increases in housing, consumer durables and business capital as incomes and sales rise."23

23Horvath & Wagner (2016) put it similarly: "Pressure from the financial industry and politicians will make it dicult for regulators to impose additional capital when excesses start to materialise." Gersbach

16

Existing research also gives some guidance on what we should expect. Antoniades & Calomiris (2018), using county-level data for the US, find that voters punish incumbent presidential candidates for credit crunches, but do not reward them for mortgage credit booms. The fear of being punished at the voting booth might make politicians particularly likely to put pressure on regulators when the economy is booming. Agur & Sharma (2013) extend this prediction to macroprudential policy: they also argue that political economy challenges are most likely during the boom, when such tools have the greatest use. The literature on economic policy reforms also usually finds that reforms often follow crises or protracted downturns, not booms (e.g. Rodrik, 1996; Abiad & Mody, 2005).

I test for heterogeneous cycles by interacting the pre-election dummy with measures of real and financial sector booms in Table 6. I standardize the interaction variables to have a mean of zero and a standard deviation of one to aid comparisons across the dierent models. In column 1, I add the interaction term with real GDP growth. The interaction term has a negative coecient of 0:021 and is highly statistically significant.

This implies that macroprudential regulation is particularly loose before elections when the economy is expanding. I next ask if this is also true for forecasts of GDP, using data from the World Bank. Mian, Sufi & Verner (2017), for example, show that such forecasts are systematically too optimistic during credit booms. I find almost equivalent point estimates in column 2. I find highly similar results for the interaction with house price growth, bank profitability, and credit growth - indicators closely monitored by financial stability authorities. Again, the interaction terms are negative and statistically significant.

Figure 3 visualizes the overall implied magnitudes of these results. These coecients are the linear combination of the pre-election dummy and its interaction with the business and financial cycle indicators (which, recall, are standardized to have a mean of zero and a standard deviation of one). These estimates can be interpreted as the election cycle during a "boom" in these variables. For comparison, I also plot the baseline election cycle estimate from table 3 (column 3). This forcefully illustrates that the electoral cycle weakens attempts to decrease the financial sector's procyclicality: macroprudential regulation is considerably looser before elections precisely when regulators are supposed to lean against the wind. Compared to the baseline estimate, sectoral regulation is more

  • Rochet (2014) argue that "in the event of excessive credit growth or risk build-ups, governments seem reluctant to use macroprudential tools ... especially if general elections are approaching."

17

than twice as loose before elections during "credit booms", i.e. when the year-on-year growth in private credit/GDP is one standard deviation above the mean.

Figure 4 plots the estimated cycle around elections during credit booms. This reveals that, during a boom, sectoral regulations are systematically looser in quarters before an election, with little noticeable reversal afterward. I find a highly similar pattern for the other indicators.24 Again, this is consistent with the interpretation that political pressures can prevent regulators from implementing countercyclical macroprudential policy.

3.4 Do Electoral Cycles Have Permanent Effects?

Up to this point, I have mainly focused on the pre-election period where most of the election-related policy changes appear to be concentrated. A crucial question is whether such cyclical eects are permanent. Put dierently: do elections merely postpone dicult macroprudential decisions or do they lead to a gradual loosening of regulation over time?

This question is challenging to answer in a cross-country setting, particularly given the relatively short time frame for which data on macroprudential tools are available. I attempt to provide some suggestive evidence in Table 7, where I introduce a dummy variable P ost Election that is equal to 1 for the two quarters after an election took place and 0 otherwise.25 The post-election dummy captures the pooled eect of the year-quarter dummies after elections in figure 2. This allows me to test formally whether regulation reverses immediately after the election by testing for the linear combination of the pre- election and post-election dummies. I continue to focus on sectoral capital buers.

The evidence appears to be broadly consistent with the idea that election-induced looser macroprudential regulation is not immediately tightened after elections. While the pre-election quarter dummy is estimated with similar magnitude and statistical sig- nificance to the main results, the coecients on the post-election dummy are considerably smaller and imprecisely estimated. What do these coecients tell us about the net eect of regulatory cycles? In the bottom rows, I compute linear combinations of the pre- and post-election dummies and test the null hypothesis that the estimated coecients sum to zero. The first observation is that the net eect is always estimated to be negative.

24These results are available upon request.

25The results are almost equivalent for dierent definitions of this dummy, e.g. if I instead assign a 1 to the three or four quarters after an election (available upon request).

18

Once I condition on country year fixed eects to mop up unobserved heterogeneity, the combined estimate also becomes statistically significant at the 10% level. While I urge caution in interpreting these results, they at least suggest the possibility that election cycles introduce a permanent bias that leads to looser regulation over time.

3.5 Robustness Tests

A concern with cross-country panel regressions is that they may not be robust to changes in estimation technique; model specification; sample composition; or dierent sets of control variables. In Table 8, I thus present a wide range of validity exercises to showcase the robustness of the coecient estimates while dierentiating between tightening and loosening episodes.

I begin by addressing concerns regarding the exact model specification and estimation technique in Panel A. The coecients are remarkably stable, independent of the included set of fixed eects or lags of the dependent variable. They also hold when using the mean group estimator (Pesaran & Smith, 1995) to account for heterogeneous slopes across countries, which suggests there is little heterogeneity in the pooled main estimates.

Since the dependent variables used here are dummies, it is common practice to use non-linear models such as logit regressions. However, I run into the problems of complete separation and incidental parameter bias due to the two-way fixed eects. Since none of the tightening episodes of the sectoral capital buer occur in pre-election quarters, it is not possible to estimate the maximum likelihood in a logit framework, which is infinity by definition. The bias-corrected estimator of Fernández-Val & Weidner (2016), however, allows for the estimation of panel logit regressions with two-way fixed eects. I also re-run the baseline estimation but restrict the sample to two quarters before and after any election. This eectively limits the "control group" to the immediate period around elections and yields a slightly larger estimated coecient for the sectoral capital buer.

In Panel B, I deal with concerns regarding sample selection. I start by dropping all countries that, at any point in the sample, are not defined as an (electoral) democracy by both Polity IV and Freedom House. As an alternative proxy for authoritarianism, I drop countries where the chief executive is a military ocer. If anything, this increases both the point estimates and statistical significance. I next drop the individual continents to validate that the findings are not driven by a particular region. I find that they are

19

not. Similarly, I also drop countries with no or very frequent changes in the dependent variable, where I define frequent changes as countries in the top 5% of the total number of changes. If anything, I find somewhat larger results here. I also divide the sample into the pre-crisis (up to 2006) and post-crisis (from 2007) period and find similar results, with somewhat larger coecients on the sectoral capital buer tightening post-crisis.

Finally, I deal with the issue of cherry-pickingcontrol variables in Panel C. I start by either including only bank controls or macro controls, or alternatively controlling for 20 (instead of 7) financial system controls from the World Bank's Global Financial Development Database. I also address the fact that the control variables are likely to be highly collinear. To overcome this issue, I separately take the first principal component of the 10 quarterly macro variables and 20 indicators of financial conditions, and control for these in the fourth row of Panel C; this also makes no dierence to the results. I can also condition on country year, country half-year or country quarter dummies, which take out unobserved variation and country-specific seasonality; this, again, makes no dierence to the results. Next, I control for the number of macroprudential tools in a given year via Cerutti et al. (2015), interacted with year-quarter dummies, which does not make a dierence, either. Finally, conditioning on detailed region time or World Bank development level time dummies also leaves the estimates unchanged.

Overall, it seems fair to conclude that a lower likelihood of a regulatory tightening of sectoral capital buers is a highly robust feature of the data.

3.6 Randomization Test

Another potential concern with attempting to identify electoral cycles is that other country- level shocks may coincide with fewer regulatory changes. But how likely would it be for such random shocks to generate my results?

I approach this question by conducting a randomization test. More specifically, I begin by picking a random quarter between the start of the sample in 2000q1 and the next hypothetical election date based on a country's constitutional term limit or common prac- tice. Consider the United States as an example, where presidential elections take place every four years. I start by picking a quarter between the first quarter of 2000 and the fourth quarter of 2003. Next, I generate placebo elections every for years until the end of the sample in 2014. If the initial placebo quarter is 2001q3, the other placebo elections

20

would be in 2005q3, 2009q3, and 2013q3.26

I create 1000 sets of these placebo election quarters and then rerun the baseline equation 1 for the tightening of sectoral capital buers, for which I find the strongest electoral cycles. Figure A3 in the online appendix plots the results of this exercise. Less than 1% of the 1000 random election quarters produce a smaller t-statistic than the one I find in the baseline specification. I conclude that unobserved country-level shocks are unlikely to drive my results.

3.7 Replication in Other Datasets

For the baseline tests, I use the data on macroprudential policy changes from Cerutti et al. (2017). The advantage of this dataset is that it uses consistent coding; has a relatively balanced and broad coverage of both countries and instruments; and has been used widely to assess the eects of macroprudential policy. Two notable alternatives include data by Kuttner & Shim (2016), who cover housing-related tools across 58 countries, and a recent eort by Budnik & Kleibl (2018), who cover 28 EU countries.27

Figure A2 shows that changes in macroprudential policy in these alternative datasets also exhibit an electoral cycle. This suggests that electoral cycles in macroprudential regulation are not limited to the particular country sample or coding of instruments in Cerutti et al. (2017).

  • What Drives Electoral Cycles in Macroprudential Policy?

Macroprudential regulation exhibits a robust and systematic electoral cycle, and this cycle is particularly pronounced during economic expansions and credit booms. In this section, I attempt to shed some light on the potential underlying mechanisms. I divide

  1. I do not code "irregular" placebo elections because their data generating process is harder to pin down. In principle, however, these should only introduce noise.
  2. Table A16 in the online appendix plots the Pearson correlation coecients between changes in macropru-
    dential tools across these three sources. The correlations are relatively low, and sometimes even negative, which likely reflects the diculty of coding regulatory actions. For changes to housing-related taxes in Budnik & Kleibl (2018) and Kuttner & Shim (2016), for example, the correlation is only 0:0644. The vari- ables that exhibit reasonably high correlations are changes to reserve requirements, risk weights, LTV ratios, and DTI ratios. But even in these cases, the correlations range between around 0:33 and 0:80. I thus treat these datasets as independent rather than merging them into one.

21

these potential channels into three broad groups: opportunistic political motives; the financial sector's political connections and regulatory capture; and uncertainty.28

4.1 Opportunistic Political Motives

Theories of opportunistic political cycles suggest that incumbent politicians attempt to influence policies to increase their chances of being re-elected (e.g. Dubois, 2016). While the exact mechanism diers, the common element of these models is that governments signal their "competence" to voters using economic fundamentals. In this section, I discuss whether models of opportunistic politicians may also go some way in explaining electoral cycles in macroprudential policy.

The evidence above already gives us some indication. First, election cycles appear to be concentrated in the tools that likely most aect the median voter. These are tools such as capital requirements on mortgages or consumer loans, as well as caps on LTV ratios. This interpretation meshes well with the observation by many policy makers that there "may be a tradeo between expanding homeownership and reducing rapid mortgage debt growth, by tightening loan-to-value ratios or raising the countercyclical capital buer" (Edge & Liang, 2017). Second, these cycles are driven by a noticeable lack of tightening during economic expansions and credit booms. This is consistent with the intuition of policy makers that politicians are particularly worried about negative eects on their re-election prospects during "good times" (e.g. Gersbach & Rochet, 2014). Third, political cycles in macroprudential regulation seem to be most pronounced before elections that are regular but expected to be close, when politicians have the largest incentives and ability to interfere with policy decisions.

Next, I consider a range of tests that, while not conclusive, also point in the direction of opportunistic political motives for cycles in macroprudential policy. These results can be found in Table 9. In column 1, I begin by introducing the interaction of pre-election quarters with the voice and accountability measure from the World Governance Indi- cators, which captures the quality of political institutions. Here and in what follows I standardize all continuous indicators to have a mean of 0 and a standard deviation of

28In unreported results, I find no evidence that party ideology, proportional representation, having a pres- idential vs. parliamentary system, or other metrics of constitutional design matter for the severity of electoral cycles.

22

  1. While the pre-election dummy continues to be negative, the interaction term is posi- tive (0:012) and statistically significant at the 5% level. It implies that a country with high voice and accountability (one standard deviation above the mean) has no election cycle in macroprudential tools compared to a country with low accountability (one standard de- viation below the mean). This implies that the electoral cycle is particularly pronounced in countries with poor political institutions.
    I consider more direct measures of potential political interference in columns 2 through
  1. In column 2, I use a proxy for state interventionism based on the frequency of state ownership of enterprises from the Fraser Institute. Higher values mean less state inter- vention. This index is also associated with a considerably more muted election cycle in macroprudential regulation. A one standard deviation increase relative to the mean al- most eliminates the cycle. In column 3, I introduce the interaction with a dummy for whether the country's central bank governor has previous work experience at the Min- istry of Finance. This measure is based on extending the dataset in Mishra & Reshef (2019) to the countries in my sample until 2017.29 I interpret it as a proxy for the per- sonal political connections of regulators. The negative (and statistically significant) inter- action term suggests that the election cycle in sectoral capital buers is concentrated in countries where regulators have closer personal linkages with politicians. In column 4, I construct a proxy for interference with bank supervision more specifically from the sur- vey data collected by Barth, Caprio & Levine (2013). They classify countries into having politically independent bank supervisors or not. The estimated coecient on the interac- tion term of 0:034 (significant at the 15% level) is almost equivalent to the estimate of the pre-election dummy itself. This suggests that there is no election cycle when supervisors are independent.30
    Last, I consider if it matters whether executives face a unified opposition. The idea be- hind this test is that politicians may not be able to "get away" with manipulating policies if they face little fractionalization in the opposition. Indeed, the estimate of the interac- tion term (0:015) suggests that political cycles in macroprudential policy are more likely when the parliamentary opposition is more fractured.

29I would like to thank Ariell Reshef for kindly sharing an updated version of their dataset with me.

30Note that this metric of political independence is based on survey data on microprudential bank regula- tors, not macroprudential institutions. I will investigate the role of the latter in section 5.

23

Figure 6 again visualizes the overall magnitudes by plotting the linear combinations of the pre-election dummy and its interaction with the proxies in Table 9. This is akin to asking what electoral cycles look like in countries with sound political institutions, low political connections of regulators, low state intervention, or considerable opposition power. In those cases, I cannot reject the null hypothesis of no electoral cycle.

In sum, electoral cycles in macroprudential tools are concentrated in regulations aimed at the median voter; stronger during economic expansions and credit booms; and driven by countries with less developed political institutions, closer personal linkages between politicians and regulators, a weak opposition, and higher state intervention in regulatory decisions. This evidence is at least consistent with the idea that opportunistic political interference may play a role for macroprudential policy.

4.2 Election Cycles, Political Connections, and Regulatory Capture

An alternative explanation for electoral regulatory cycles that is unrelated to concerns about the median voter could be regulatory capture (Stigler, 1971). A large literature has established that political connectedness of firms is a pervasive feature of economies around the world (Faccio, 2006). Such connections are used both by politicians to reallocate funds (e.g. Schoenherr, 2017) and by firms to reward or help politicians (e.g. Bertrand et al., 2018; Chavaz & Rose, 2018). Adelino & Dinc (2014), for example, show that nonfinancial firms with weaker fundamentals lobbied more during the financial crisis of 2008 and were subsequently allocated more government funds. Akey (2015) shows that pre-election donations to politicians increase firm values when the preferred candidate wins. More broadly, financial regulation is often seen as the outcome of political bargaining between banks and governments (e.g. Valuing Changes in Political Networks: Evidence from Campaign Contributions to Close Congressional Elections, Raj; Calomiris

  • Haber, 2014). Political connections may also interact with the electoral cycle: incum- bent governments could signal "good will" to financial sector actors by loosening policy while fundraising.
    I test the validity of this hypothesis in explaining election cycles in macroprudential regulation by again introducing an interaction term with pre-election quarters, this time based on dierent proxies for the connectedness and lobbying power of a country's fi- nancial sector. Some of these proxies directly attempt to measure political connections.

24

Others are based on variables that are plausibly correlated with the intensity of financial sector lobbying.

Table 10 reports the results for changes in sectoral capital buers. In column 1, I begin by introducing the interaction with a measure of banking sector concentration. One would expect that more concentrated sectors with a few powerful institutions wield more lobbying power.31 Column 2 uses a more direct measure of lobbying. Specifically, I construct a country-level index based on data from the Political Finance Database of the Institute for Democracy and Electoral Assistance. The index counts whether a country has "bans and limits on private income"; "spending regulations"; and "reporting, oversight, and sanctions." In both specifications, the coecients on the interaction of pre-election quarters with these measures are small and statistically indistinguishable from zero.

Next, I consider whether political connections matter. In column 3, I use the share of politically connected firms (by market capitalization) constructed by Faccio (2006) as an indicator for linkages between private firms and the government. This measure is supposed to capture the prevalence of "revolving doors" but is not specific to the financial sector. Again, the interaction term is close to zero and also has the "wrong" sign, indicating that higher connections mitigate the cycle. In column 4, I use a measure on the political connections of banks from Braun & Raddatz (2010). This "connected banks" variable captures the share of banks with at least one former politician on the board of directors. Again, the interaction term is clearly insignificant.32 As a last check, in column 5, I again draw on the newly collected extended data building on Mishra & Reshef (2019). In particular, I introduce an interaction with whether a country's central bank governor has previous work experience in the financial sector. The coecient on the interaction here has the "wrong" sign and again is statistically insignificant.

While the results based on these proxies should be taken with a grain of salt, the regulatory cycle around elections does not appear to reflect interference aimed at financial institutions. The evidence thus continues to point to government interference aimed at the median voter.

31The results here are similar when using other measures of competition, namely the Boone indicator, H-statistic, or Lerner index (available upon request).

32I find equivalent results using the other, closely related metrics from Braun & Raddatz (2010).

25

4.3 Electoral Cycles and Uncertainty

A third potential explanation for observing election cycles in macroprudential tools could be uncertainty about future government policy. This uncertainty could decrease firm investment prior to elections, which may in turn aect regulation. Julio & Yook (2012) and Jens (2017), for example, find that firm investment is lower in the run-up to elections, especially for those with uncertain outcomes. They show that this most likely reflects uncertainty about future government policies. Canes-Wrone& Park (2012) develop this intuition into a model and also find lower private investment prior to close elections in a panel of OECD economies (also see Canes-Wrone & Park, 2014).33 If regulators observe lower investment, they may choose to forgo tighter macroprudential policies even in the absence of political interference.

Three reasons make it unlikely that uncertainty is the driving factor behind the electoral cycle in macroprudential policy. First, I do not find a systematic cycle in the macroeconomic fundamentals in my sample, including the ratio of private investment to GDP. Second, I only find robust evidence for electoral cycles in tools aimed at households, not broader tools that may equally impact firms. While there may be general equilibrium eects, Canes-Wrone & Ponce de Leon (2018) find, if anything, some evidence for higher consumption in pre-election periods; in my sample, the data show no dierences in consumption around elections.

Third, and most importantly, I find no evidence that the electoral cycle in macro- prudential tools varies with the level of or change in economic policy uncertainty prior to elections. In Table 11, I plot the results from introducing an interaction term with four well-known measures of uncertainty: the standardized Economic Policy Uncertainty (EPU) index from Baker et al. (2016); the World Uncertainty Index (WUI) from Ahir et al. (2018); stock price volatility (see e.g. Bloom, 2009); and the option-implied volatility of the S&P 500 index (VIX).34 The interaction terms of interest are positive, small, and far from conventional levels of statistical significance for all measures - inconsistent with

33A largely separate literature in finance studies the asset pricing implications of uncertainty about government policy; recent work includes Ľuboš Pástor & Veronesi (2012), Pástor & Veronesi (2013), and Kelly, Ľuboš Pástor & Veronesi (2016).

34Because the Economic Policy Uncertainty index is only available for a sub-group of countries, I assign the value of the aggregate European EPU to EU countries for which I do not have data. I also assign the values for China to Taiwan. This adjustment does not drive the results shown here.

26

the "waiting out" hypothesis. In the online appendix Table A13, I show similar results for changes in these uncertainty measures. I conclude that uncertainty about future economic policies is unlikely to drive the electoral cycle in macroprudential regulation.

A related explanation for an electoral cycle could be legislative inertia, e.g. because regulators or governments pursue a "hands-o" approach when elections are approach- ing. It is, however, unclear why this should lead to a change in the overall regulatory stance. Legislative inertia would predict a lower likelihood of loosening and tightening policy, but I only find evidence for the latter. Also, it is less clear why inertia should be more important during booms or concentrated in tools aimed at the median voter.

5 Institutional Frameworks and Macroprudential Policy

Do institutional frameworks matter for the politics of macroprudential regulation? In the case of monetary policy, a broad consensus holds that central bank independence is an eective means of insulating policy decisions from political interference (see e.g. Cukierman, 1992; Eijnger & de Haan, 1996; Crowe & Meade, 2007). A widespread assumption appears to be that central banks are thus also uniquely suited to implement countercyclical macroprudential policy. To quote the former director of the IMF's Monetary and Capital Markets Department, José Viñals, "... in many countries the central bank is unique in being insulated from lobbying and political pressures, which is important to make macroprudential policy work" (Viñals, 2013). The optimal design of governance for macroprudential tools, however, is subject to an ongoing debate.

There are several reasons to suspect that independent central banks may not be in an ideal position to "tame" regulatory cycles in targeted instruments. First, we may be able to draw some lessons from countries' experiences with credit controls, which are in many ways historical precursors of macroprudential tools (Elliott, Feldberg & Lehnert, 2013; Kelber & Monnet, 2014; Fischer, 2014). Kane (1977), for example, argues that targeted policies are fundamentally dierent from the "meat-ax" of monetary policy because the "discriminatory eects of aggregate policies (e.g. on housing) are unintentional". According to Kane, such targeted policies are thus more likely to be hijacked for political pur- poses.35 Second, in contrast to monetary policy, the eect of many types of macropruden-

35Koetter, Roszbach & Spagnolo (2014) find that central bank control over prudential supervision is not

27

tial tools can be easily undone by fiscal authorities. A tightening of LTV ratios, for exam- ple, could easily be counteracted by a decrease in stamp duties on housing transactions. This might reduce the leeway independent central banks and other financial regulators have over macroprudential policy. It also serves as an argument for why governments should potentially have a vote in deciding macroprudential regulation: if politicians have a say in regulatory decisions, they may be more inclined to work with regulators on solutions that enhance financial stability without large costs on the median voter (see e.g. Tucker, 2016, 2018). Third, many of the cautionary tales about political pressures in the design of financial regulation are set in countries with arguably excellent institutions by international comparison, such as the United States, the United Kingdom, Germany, Ire- land, or Spain (Dagher, 2017; Calomiris & Haber, 2014; Fernández-Villaverde, Garicano & Santos, 2013; Dubois, 2016).

I conduct an empirical test by introducing interaction terms with dierent measures of institutional frameworks for macroprudential policy in Table 12. I begin by looking at whether a country has a "financial stability committee" in columns 1 and 2 using data from Edge & Liang (2017); around half of the countries in my sample have one. These committees can consist of representatives of dierent regulatory agencies (the central bank, securities regulators, prudential regulators), as well as the government. They also dier by whether they have a pure advisory role or can actually implement policies.36 I find that financial stability committees matter for election cycles in macroprudential tools, but only if they can implement policies: the estimated coecient of 0:039 in column 2 (significant at the 5% level) suggests that having a powerful committee fully mitigates the election cycle in sectoral capital buers.

Next, I turn my attention to who bears the main responsibility for implementing macroprudential policy. In column 3, I find no evidence that electoral cycles are less pronounced in countries where macroprudential tools are mainly decided on by the central bank in column 4 (drawing on data from Cerutti et al. (2015)). This can be seen as a first indication that macroprudential may dier from monetary policy. In columns 4

associated with cross-country dierences in non-performing loans during the 2007-2008 crisis.

36For both types of committees (advisory and equipped with decision-making powers), I create a dummy variable that is equal to 1 for countries that have a committee, and 0 otherwise. The results, however, are not driven by the fact that some countries do not have a committee; they are almost equivalent in the subsample of countries that have one (available upon request).

28

through 7, I then restrict the sample to countries where the central bank has the main decision powers and investigate the role of central bank independence.37 These results suggest that higher central bank independence or transparency make little dierence for the electoral cycle. The point estimates are far from statistically significant and close to zero in most cases; they are negative for the transparency measures. Even the largest positive point estimate on the interaction term in column 4 suggests a limited role for central bank governance: independence would have to increase by almost three standard deviations to undo the election cycle.

I provide some additional evidence on the potential role of central bank independence in the online appendix (Table A14). Here, I rerun the regressions in columns 4 through 7 in the full sample (including countries where central banks do not decide on macro- prudential tools). I also run them in the sample where central banks have little say over macroprudential regulation.38 This exercise broadly confirms the results in Table 12. If anything, central bank independence appears to matter more in the sample where they have little decision-making power over macroprudential tools.

Could it be that central bank independence does not matter for the countries in my sample at all? As a type of placebo test, I build on previous studies (e.g. Block, 2002; Alpanda & Honig, 2009) and replace the dependent variable with two simple measures of monetary policy: the policy rate and the growth in central bank reserves. This is equivalent to asking whether, in the same sample, central bank independence is a moderating factor for political cycles in monetary policy. Importantly, recall the finding from 2.3 that the monetary policy measures I use here do not exhibit an electoral cycle on average.39

Table A15 in the online appendix presents the results of this exercise. The interaction term P re election CBI is statistically significant in all specifications.40 The coecient signs suggest that central bank independence decreases electoral pressures for monetary

  1. I also drop the Eurozone countries from these regressions. The reason is that the central bank indepen- dence metrics refer to the European Central Bank; in the Eurozone, the national authorities are mostly in charge of macroprudential regulation. As such, the estimates from regressions including the Eurozone would not be informative about a potential role of central bank governance per se.
  2. I also consider an additional metric of de jure central bank independence from Garriga (2016).

39More accurately, section 2.3 shows that there is no electoral cycle in central bank reserves or the money market interest rate. Because the money market interest rate and central bank policy rate have a Pearson correlation coecient of 0.83, I do not find an average electoral cycle for the policy rate, either (t = 0:19).

40I test for election cycles separately in a sample with and without the Eurozone. When the Eurozone is included, I treat it as a single country. See Table A15 for details.

29

policy. For the policy rate in column 3, for example, the estimate of 0:307 on the pre- election dummy suggests central banks are more likely to ease monetary policy prior to elections; the interaction term of 0:773 indicates that this eect is mitigated by central bank independence. Similarly, the growth in central bank reserves is higher in quarters before elections, but considerably less so when central banks are more independent.

Taken together, the results presented in this section suggest that while central bank independence is eective in mitigating electoral cycles in monetary policy, it may not be so for macroprudential policy. I do, however, find some role for powerful financial stability committees. This can be interpreted as some evidence that macroprudential institutions should also have a role for other players, potentially including government ocials (Fischer, 2015; Tucker, 2016).

  • Conclusion

Macroprudential measures have become an increasingly important part of the macroeconomic policy toolkit. There is widespread agreement in central banks, financial regula- tors, and academia that such tools should play a role in limiting the build-up of systemic risk with to prevent banking crises or at least softening their impact.

While a rapidly growing academic literature studies the desirability and eects of such policies, we only have anecdotal evidence on the potential political limitations in implementing them. This paper takes a first step forward by showing that changes in macroprudential tools exhibit a systematic electoral cycle. The correlations I document are not driven by strategic election timing and unlikely to be driven by economic or fi- nancial fundamentals. Instead, a large number of cross-sectional tests is most consistent with the interpretation that tightening the policies most directly aimed at the median voter is politically costly, particularly when elections are approaching.

I also find the electoral cycle is most pronounced during economic expansions and credit booms, when past crises may seem more distant (Reinhart & Rogo, 2009; Mal- mendier & Nagel, 2011). This can be rationalized in models of opportunistic political cycles in which incumbent governments want to avoid deteriorating fundamentals that they can use to signal competency to voters. Of course, the very point of macroprudential tools is to be countercyclical. My results thus suggest that political pressures may inhibit

30

regulators' ability to implement these policies as envisioned.

While monetary policy is considerably less sensitive to upcoming elections in countries with independent central banks, I find little evidence that central banks are uniquely insulated from political pressures in implementing macroprudential policy. One potential explanation for these dierences is that targeted credit policies may have much more obvious distributional eects than monetary policy (Kohn, 2014; Fischer, 2015), as argued more than 40 years ago by Kane (1977).

The findings presented here call for more research into the politics of financial stability frameworks. If political interference in the use of prudential regulation is a constraint, this raises the question which institutional setups can mitigate them. I find some evidence that financial stability committees could make a dierence. The results also raise the question of how granular macroprudential tools should be, since it is targeted tools that exhibit a clear electoral cycle, and further which role monetary policy should play in the build-up of systemic risks. Haldane (2017) stresses that, in light of political economy questions, "there is a debate to be had ... about the appropriate degree of discretion to confer on regulators". I hope the evidence I present makes a first empirical contribution to this debate.

31

References

Abiad, A. & Mody, A. (2005). Financial Reform: What Shakes It? What Shapes It? The American Economic Review, 95(1), 66-88.

Abrams, B. A. (2006). How Richard Nixon Pressured Arthur Burns: Evidence from the Nixon Tapes. Journal of Economic Perspectives, 20(4), 177-188.

Adelino, M. & Dinc, I. S. (2014). Corporate Distress and Lobbying: Evidence from the Stimulus Act. Journal of Financial Economics, 114(2), 256 - 272.

Agur, I. & Sharma, S. (2013). Rules, Discretion, and Macro-Prudential Policy. IMF Working Papers 13/65, International Monetary Fund.

Ahir, H., Bloom, N., & Furceri, D. (2018). The World Uncertainty Index. Mimeo.

Aikman, D., Haldane, A. G., & Nelson, B. D. (2015). Curbing the Credit Cycle. The Economic Journal, 125(585), 1072-1109.

Aiyar, S., Calomiris, C., & Wieladek, T. (2014). Does Macro-Prudential Regulation Leak? Evidence from a UK Policy Experiment. Journal of Money, Credit and Banking, 46(s1), 181-214.

Aiyar, S., Calomiris, C. W., & Wieladek, T. (2016). How Does Credit Supply Respond to Monetary Policy and Bank Minimum Capital Requirements? European Economic Review, 82(C), 142-165.

Akey, P. (2015). Valuing Changes in Political Networks: Evidence from Campaign Contributions to Close Congressional Elections. The Review of Financial Studies, 28(11), 3188-3223.

Akey, P., Dobridge, C., Heimer, R., & Lewellen, S. (2018). Pushing Boundaries: Political Redistricting and Consumer Credit. Technical report.

Akey, P., Heimer, R., & Lewellen, S. (2018). Politicizing Consumer Credit. Technical report.

Akhmedov, A. & Zhuravskaya, E. (2004). Opportunistic Political Cycles: Test in a Young Democracy Setting. The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 119(4), 1301-1338.

Akinci, O. & Olmstead-Rumsey, J. (2015). How Eective are Macroprudential Policies? An Empirical Investigation. International Finance Discussion Papers 1136.

Alesina, A., Cohen, G. D., & Roubini, N. (1992). Macroeconomic Policy and Elections in Oecd Democracies. Economics & Politics, 4(1), 1-30.

Alesina, A. & Paradisi, M. (2017). Political Budget Cycles: Evidence from Italian Cities. Economics & Politics.

Alpanda, S. & Honig, A. (2009). The Impact of Central Bank Independence on Political Monetary Cycles in Advanced and Developing Nations. Journal of Money, Credit and Banking, 41(7), 1365-1389.

Altunbas, Y., Binici, M., & Gambacorta, L. (2018). Macroprudential policy and bank risk. Journal of International Money and Finance, 81(C), 203-220.

Antoniades, A. & Calomiris, C. W. (2018). Mortgage Market Credit Conditions and U.S. Presidential Elec- tions. Working Paper 24459.

Armingeon, K., Wenger, V., Wiedemeier, F., Isler, C., Knöpfel, L., Weisstanner, D., & Engler, S. (2017). Comparative Political Data Set 1960-2015.Bern: Institute of Political Science, University of Berne.

Ayyagari, M., Beck, T., & Peria, M. S. M. (2017). Credit Growth and Macroprudential Policies: Preliminary Evidence on the Firm Level. In B. for International Settlements (Ed.), Financial Systems and the Real Economy, volume 91 of BIS Papers chapters (pp. 15-34). Bank for International Settlements.

Baker, S. R., Bloom, N., & Davis, S. J. (2016). Measuring Economic Policy Uncertainty. The Quarterly Journal

32

of Economics, 131(4), 1593-1636.

Barth, J. R., Caprio, Gerard, J., & Levine, R. (2013). Bank Regulation and Supervision in 180 Countries from 1999 to 2011. Working Paper 18733, National Bureau of Economic Research.

Beck, T., Clarke, G., Gro, A., & Keefer, P. (2001). New Tools in Comparative Political Economy. World Bank Economic Review, 15(1), 165-175.

Behn, M., Haselmann, R., Kick, T., & Vig, V. (2015). The Political Economy of Bank Bailouts. IMFS Working Paper Series 86.

Benmelech, E. & Moskowitz, T. J. (2010). The Political Economy of Financial Regulation: Evidence from U.S. State Usury Laws in the 19th Century. The Journal of Finance, 65(3), 1029-1073.

Bertrand, M., Kramarz, F., Schoar, A., & Thesmar, D. (2018). The Cost of Political Connections. Review of Finance, 22(3), 849-876.

Bianchi, J. (2011). Overborrowing and Systemic Externalities in the Business Cycle. American Economic Review, 101(7), 3400-3426.

Bianchi, J. & Mendoza, E. G. (2018). Optimal Time-Consistent Macroprudential Policy. Journal of Political Economy, 126(2), 588-634.

BIS (2017). Macroprudential frameworks, implementation and relationship with other policies. Number 94 in BIS Papers. Bank for International Settlements.

Block, S. A. (2002). Political Business Cycles, Democratization, and Economic Reform: The Case of Africa. Journal of Development Economics, 67(1), 205 - 228.

Bloom, N. (2009). The Impact of Uncertainty Shocks. Econometrica, 77(3), 623-685.

Brancati, D. (2017). Global Elections Database. New York: New York: Global Elections Database, Date Accessed 08/01/2017. Website: Http://www.globalelectionsdatabase.com.

Braun, M. & Raddatz, C. (2008). The Politics of Financial Development: Evidence from Trade Liberaliza- tion. The Journal of Finance, 63(3), 1469-1508.

Braun, M. & Raddatz, C. (2010). Banking on Politics: When Former High-ranking Politicians Become Bank Directors. World Bank Economic Review, 24(2), 234-279.

Brown, C. & Dinc, S. (2005). The Politics of Bank Failures: Evidence from Emerging Markets. 120, 1413- 1444.

Budnik, K. & Kleibl, J. (2018). Macroprudential Regulation in the European Union in 1995-2014: Introducing a New Data Set on Policy Actions of a Macroprudential Nature. Working Paper Series 2123.

Calomiris, C. & Haber, S. H. (2014). Fragile by Design: The Political Origins of Banking Crises and Scarce Credit (1 ed.). Princeton University Press.

Canes-Wrone, B. & Park, J.-K. (2012). Electoral Business Cycles in Oecd Countries. The American Political Science Review, 106(1), 103-122.

Canes-Wrone, B. & Park, J.-K. (2014). Elections, Uncertainty and Irreversible Investment. British Journal of Political Science, 44(1), 83-106.

Canes-Wrone, B. & Ponce de Leon, C. (2018). Electoral Cycles and Democratic Development. Technical report.

Carvalho, D. (2014). The Real Eects of Government-owned Banks: Evidence from an Emerging Market. The Journal of Finance, 69(2), 577-609.

Cerutti, E., Correa, R., Fiorentino, E., & Segalla, E. (2017). Changes in Prudential Policy Instruments - A New Cross-Country Database. International Journal of Central Banking, 13(2), 477-503.

33

Cerutti, E. M., Claessens, S., & Laeven, L. (2015). The Use and Eectiveness of Macroprudential Policies: New Evidence. IMF Working Papers 15/61.

Chavaz, M. & Rose, A. K. (2018). Political Borders and Bank Lending in Post-crisis America. Review of Finance, rfy027.

Clark, W. R. & Hallerberg, M. (2000). Mobile Capital, Domestic Institutions, and Electorally Induced Monetary and Fiscal Policy. The American Political Science Review, 94(2), 323-346.

Cole, S. (2009). Fixing Market Failures or Fixing Elections? Agricultural Credit in India. American Economic Journal: Applied Economics, 1(1), 219-50.

Crowe, C. & Meade, E. E. (2007). The Evolution of Central Bank Governance around the World. Journal of Economic Perspectives, 21(4), 69-90.

Cruz, C., Keefer, P., & Scartascini, C. (2018). Database of Political Institutions 2017 (DPI2017). Inter- American Development Bank. Numbers for Development. Available at: https://mydata.iadb.org/Reform- Modernization-of-the-State/Database-of-Political-Institutions-2017/938i-s2bw.

Cukierman, A. (1992). Central Bank Strategy, Credibility, and Independence: Theory and Evidence (1 ed.)., volume 1. The MIT Press.

Dagher, J. C. (2017). Regulatory Cycles: Revisiting the Political Economy of Financial Crises (October 18, 2017). Available at SSRN: https://ssrn.com/abstract=2772373.

Dam, L. & Koetter, M. (2012). Bank Bailouts and Moral Hazard: Evidence from Germany. The Review of Financial Studies, 25(8), 2343-2380.

Dinc, S. (2005). Politicians and Banks: Political Influences on Government-owned Banks in Emerging Markets. Journal of Financial Economics, 453-479.

Dincer, N. N. & Eichengreen, B. (2014). Central Bank Transparency and Independence: Updates and New Measures. International Journal of Central Banking, 10(1), 189-259.

Doerr, S., Gissler, S., Peydro, J.-L., & Voth, H.-J. (2018). From Finance to Fascism: The Real Eect of Germany's 1931 Banking Crisis. Available at SSRN: https://ssrn.com/abstract=3146746.

Drazen, A. (2000). The Political Business Cycle After 25 Years. Nber Macroeconomics Annual, 15, 75-117.

Dubois, E. (2016). Political Business Cycles 40 Years After Nordhaus. Public Choice, 166(1), 235-259.

Edge, R. M. & Liang, N. (2017). Who Is in Charge of Financial Stability, Why, and What They Can Do. Brooking Institute Working Paper.

Eijnger, S. & de Haan, J. (1996). The Political Economy of Central-bank Independence. Princeton studies in international economics.

Elliott, D. J., Feldberg, G., & Lehnert, A. (2013). The history of cyclical macroprudential policy in the United States. Finance and Economics Discussion Series 2013-29.

Englmaier, F. & Stowasser, T. (2017). Electoral Cycles in Savings Bank Lending. Journal of the European Economic Association, 15(2), 296-354.

Epstein, D. L., Bates, R., Goldstone, J., Kristensen, I., & O'Halloran, S. (2006). Democratic Transitions. American Journal of Political Science, 50(3), 551-569.

Epure, M., Mihai, I., Minoiu, C., & Peydró, J.-L. (2017). Household Credit, Global Financial Cycle, and Macroprudential Policies: Credit Register Evidence from an Emerging Country. Working Papers 1006.

Faccio, M. (2006). Politically Connected Firms. American Economic Review, 96(1), 369-386.

Farhi, E. & Werning, I. (2016). A Theory of Macroprudential Policies in the Presence of Nominal Rigidities. Econometrica, 84(5), 1645-1704.

34

Fernández-Val, I. & Weidner, M. (2016). Individual and Time Eects in Nonlinear Panel Models with Large N, T. Journal of Econometrics, 192(1), 291 - 312.

Fernández-Villaverde, J., Garicano, L., & Santos, T. (2013). Political Credit Cycles: The Case of the Euro- zone. Journal of Economic Perspectives, 27(3), 145-166.

Financial Times (2019). Martin Wolf: Why further financial crises are inevitable. March 19, 2019. Available online at:https://www.ft.com/content/d9d94f4a-4884-11e9-bbc9-6917dce3dc62.

Fischer, S. (2014).

Financial Sector

Reform: How Far Are We?

Speech at the Martin

Feldstein Lecture, National Bureau of

Economic Research, Cambridge, Massachusetts. Available at:

https://www.federalreserve.gov/newsevents/speech/fischer20140710a.htm.

Fischer, S. (2015). Financial Sector Reform: How Far Are We? Speech at the 2015 Herbert Stein Memorial Lecture, National Economists Club, Washington DC, 4 November 2015. Available at: https://www.bis.org/review/r151109c.htm.

Foremny, D. & Riedel, N. (2014). Business Taxes and the Electoral Cycle. Journal of Public Economics, 115(Supplement C), 48 - 61.

Funke, M., Schularick, M., & Trebesch, C. (2016). Going to extremes: Politics after financial crises, 1870-2014.European Economic Review, 88, 227 - 260. SI: The Post-Crisis Slump.

Gambacorta, L. & Murcia, A. (2017). The impact of macroprudential policies and their interaction with monetary policy: an empirical analysis using credit registry data. CEPR Discussion Papers 12027.

Garriga, A. C. (2016). Central Bank Independence in the World: A New Data Set. International Interactions, 42(5), 849-868.

German Council of Economic Experts (2017). Annual Report 2017=2018. Chapter 5: Financial Markets: Gaps in Regulation, Growing Risk. Available at https://www.sachverstaendigenrat- wirtschaft.de/fileadmin/dateiablage/gutachten/jg201718/Chapter_5.pdf.

Gersbach, H. & Rochet, J.-C. (2014). Capital Regulation and Credit Fluctuations. In D. Schoenmaker (Ed.), Macroprudentialism: A Voxeu.org Ebook (pp. 89-95). CEPR Press.

Gourinchas, P.-O. & Obstfeld, M. (2012). Stories of the Twentieth Century for the Twenty-First.American Economic Journal: Macroeconomics, 4(1), 226-265.

Gyongyosi, G. & Verner, E. (2019). Financial Crisis, Creditor-Debtor Conflict, and Political Extremism. Available at SSRN: https://ssrn.com/abstract=3289741.

Haldane, A. (2017). Rethinking Financial Stability. Speech Given at the 'rethinking Macroeconomic Policy Iv' Conference, Washington, D.c., Peterson Institute for International Economics.

Halling, M., Pichler, P., & Stomper, A. (2016). The Politics of Related Lending. Journal of Financial and Quantitative Analysis, 51(1), 333-358.

Haselmann, R., Schoenherr, D., & Vig, V. (2018). Rent Seeking in Elite Networks. Journal of Political Economy, 126(4), 1638-1690.

Havrilesky, T. (1988). Monetary Policy Signaling from the Administration to the Federal Reserve. Journal of Money, Credit and Banking, 20(1), 83-101.

Herrera, H., Ordoñez, G., & Trebesch, C. (2014). Political Booms, Financial Crises. Working Paper 20346.

Horvath, B. & Wagner, W. (2016). Macroprudential Policies and the Lucas Critique. In B. f. I. Settlements (Ed.), Macroprudential Policy, volume 86 (pp. 39-44). Bank for International Settlements.

Igan, D., Lambert, T., Wagner, W., & Zhang, Q. (2017). Winning Connections? Special Interests and the Sale of Failed Banks. IMF Working Papers 17/262.

IMF (2011). Macroprudential Policy; What Instruments and How to Use them? Lessons From Country

35

Experiences. IMF Working Papers 11/238.

IMF (2017). Global Financial Stability Report October 2017: Is Growth at Risk? Technical report.

Irish Times (2007). McDowell backs stamp duty package by summer. April 21, 2007. Available online at:https://www.irishtimes.com/news/mcdowell-backs-stamp-duty-package-by-summer-1.1202797.

Ito, T. (1990). The Timing of Elections and Political Business Cycles in Japan. Journal of Asian Economics, 1(1), 135 - 156.

Jeanne, O. & Korinek, A. (2018). Managing Credit Booms and Busts: A Pigouvian Taxation Approach. Journal of Monetary Economics.

Jens, C. E. (2017). Political Uncertainty and Investment: Causal Evidence from U.S. Gubernatorial Elec- tions. Journal of Financial Economics, 124(3), 563-579.

Jiménez, G., Ongena, S., Peydró, J.-L., & Saurina, J. (2017). Macroprudential Policy, Countercyclical Bank Capital Buers, and Credit Supply: Evidence from the Spanish Dynamic Provisioning Experiments. Journal of Political Economy, 125(6), 2126-2177.

Johnson, S. & Mitton, T. (2003). Cronyism and Capital Controls: Evidence from Malaysia. Journal of Financial Economics, 67(2), 351 - 382.

Julio, B. & Yook, Y. (2012). Political Uncertainty and Corporate Investment Cycles. The Journal of Finance, 67(1), 45-83.

Kane, E. J. (1977). Good Intentions and Unintended Evil: The Case against Selective Credit Allocation. Journal of Money, Credit and Banking, 9(1), 55-69.

Keech, W. R. (1995). Economic Politics: The Costs of Democracy (1 ed.). Cambridge University Press.

Kelber, A. & Monnet, E. (2014). Macroprudential policy and quantitative instruments: a European historical perspective. Financial Stability Review, (18), 151-160.

Kelly, B., Ľuboš Pástor, & Veronesi, P. (2016). The Price of Political Uncertainty: Theory and Evidence from the Option Market. Journal of Finance, 71(5), 2417-2480.

Khwaja, A. I. & Mian, A. (2005). Do Lenders Favor Politically Connected Firms? Rent Provision in an Emerging Financial Market. The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 120(4), 1371-1411.

Kindleberger, C. (1978). Manias, Panics, and Crashes: A History of Financial Crises. Basic Books.

Koetter, M. & Popov, A. (2019). Political Cycles in Bank Government Lending. Technical report.

Koetter, M., Roszbach, K., & Spagnolo, G. (2014). Financial Stability and Central Bank Governance. International Journal of Central Banking, 10(4), 31-68.

Kohn, D. (2014). Institutions for Macroprudential Regulation: The UK and the U.S. Available at:https://www.brookings.edu/on-the-record/institutions-for-macroprudential-regulation-the-uk-and-the-u-s/.

Korinek, A. & Simsek, A. (2016). Liquidity Trap and Excessive Leverage. American Economic Review, 106(3), 699-738.

Kroszner, R. S. & Strahan, P. E. (1999). What Drives Deregulation? Economics and Politics of the Relaxation of Bank Branching Restrictions. The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 114(4), 1437-1467.

Kuttner, K. & Shim, I. (2016). Can Non-interest Rate Policies Stabilize Housing Markets? Evidence from a Panel of 57 Economies. Journal of Financial Stability, 26(C), 31-44.

Lorenzoni, G. (2008). Inecient Credit Booms. The Review of Economic Studies, 75(3), 809-833.

MacRae, C. (1977). A Political Model of the Business Cycle. Journal of Political Economy, 85(2), 239-63.

Malmendier, U. & Nagel, S. (2011). Depression Babies: Do Macroeconomic Experiences Aect Risk Taking? The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 126(1), 373-416.

36

Mian, A., Sufi, A., & Trebbi, F. (2010). The Political Economy of the US Mortgage Default Crisis. American Economic Review, 100(5), 1967-98.

Mian, A., Sufi, A., & Trebbi, F. (2013). The Political Economy of the Subprime Mortgage Credit Expansion. Quarterly Journal of Political Science, 8(4), 373-408.

Mian, A., Sufi, A., & Verner, E. (2017). Household Debt and Business Cycles Worldwide. The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 132(4), 1755-1817.

Mishra, P. & Reshef, A. (2019). How Do Central Bank Governors Matter? Regulation and the Financial Sector. Journal of Money, Credit and Banking, 51(2-3),369-402.

Nordhaus, W. D. (1975). The Political Business Cycle. Review of Economic Studies, 42(2), 169-190. Persson, T. & Tabellini, G. (2003). The Economic Eects of Constitutions. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press.

Pesaran, M. H. & Smith, R. (1995). Estimating long-run relationships from dynamic heterogeneous panels. Journal of Econometrics, 68(1), 79-113.

Pástor, u. & Veronesi, P. (2013). Political Uncertainty and Risk Premia. Journal of Financial Economics, 110(3), 520 - 545.

Rajan, R. G. & Zingales, L. (2003). The Great Reversals: The Politics of Financial Development in the Twentieth Century. Journal of Financial Economics, 69(1), 5 - 50. Tuck Symposium on Corporate Governance.

Reinhart, C. M. & Rogo, K. S. (2009). This Time Is Dierent: Eight Centuries of Financial Folly. Number 8973 in Economics Books. Princeton University Press.

Rodrik, D. (1996). Understanding Economic Policy Reform. Journal of Economic Literature, 34(1), 9-41. Rogo, K. (1990). Equilibrium Political Budget Cycles. American Economic Review, 80(1), 21-36.

Rogo, K. & Sibert, A. (1988). Elections and Macroeconomic Policy Cycles. Review of Economic Studies, 55(1), 1-16.

Sapienza, P. (2004). The Eects of Government Ownership on Bank Lending. Journal of Financial Economics, 72(2), 357 - 384.

Schmitt-Grohé, S. & Uribe, M. (2016). Downward Nominal Wage Rigidity, Currency Pegs, and Involuntary Unemployment. Journal of Political Economy, 124(5), 1466-1514.

Schoenherr, D. (2017). Political Connections and Allocative Distortions. Technical report.

Schularick, M. & Taylor, A. M. (2012). Credit Booms Gone Bust: Monetary Policy, Leverage Cycles, and Financial Crises, 1870-2008.American Economic Review, 102(2), 1029-1061.

Schultz, K. A. (1995). The Politics of the Political Business Cycle. British Journal of Political Science, 25(1), 79-99.

Shi, M. & Svensson, J. (2006). Political Budget Cycles: Do They Dier Across Countries and Why? Journal of Public Economics, 90(8-9),1367-1389.

Stigler, G. J. (1971). The Theory of Economic Regulation. The Bell Journal of Economics and Management Science, 2(1), 3-21.

Tucker, P. (2016). The Design and Governance of Financial Stability Regimes: A Challenge to Technical Know-how, Democratic Accountability and International Coordination. Technical report, Center for International Governance Innovation.

Tucker, P. (2018). Unelected Power: The Quest for Legitimacy in Central Banking and the Regulatory State (1 ed.). Princeton University Press.

Tufte, E. R. (1978). Political Control of the Economy (1 ed.). Princeton University Press.

Ľuboš Pástor & Veronesi, P. (2012). Uncertainty about Government Policy and Stock Prices. The Journal of

37

Finance, 67(4), 1219-1264.

Viñals, J. (2013). Making Macroprudential Policy Work. Remarks by José Viñals at Brookings. Available at https://www.imf.org/en/News/Articles/2015/09/28/04/53/sp091613.

38

Figures

Figure 1: Changes in Macroprudential Policy, by Pre-Election Quarter

Change in Sectoral Capital Buffers

0.012

0.010

0.005

0.000

−0.005

−0.010

−0.009

Pre−election quarter

Change in Prudential Index

0.06

0.050

0.04

0.031

0.02

0.00

All other quarters

Notes: This figure plots average changes in sector-specific capital buers and the macroprudential regulation index in pre-election quarters and all other quarters. Positive values indicate regulatory tightening, negative values loosening. The source of the macroprudential policy data is Cerutti et al. (2017).

39

Figure 2: Elections and Macroprudential Regulation

0.06

0.04

0.02

0.00

−0.02

−0.04

−0.06

−4

−3

−2

−1

0

1

2

3

4

Quarters since election

Notes: This figure plots changes in sectoral capital buers around elections. I plot the estimated OLS coecients ˆh of the following regression:

4

hX

Rit = i + t +

hElectionit + X0+ Rit1 + "it

=4

The regression also includes one lag of the dependent variable. 95% confidence intervals are based on standard errors clustered by country.

40

Figure 3: Electoral Cycles and Procyclical Regulation

0.00

−0.02

−0.04

−0.041

−0.06

−0.064

−0.067

−0.068

−0.069

−0.08

−0.086

−0.10

−0.12

Baseline

High

High

High

High

High

estimate

GDP

GDP

house price

bank

credit

growth

forecast

growth

ROE

growth

Notes: This figure plots changes in sectoral capital buers in pre-election quarters during economic expansions and financial sector booms. More specifically, I plot the linear combination of the estimated OLS coecients ˆ1 + ˆ2 of the following regression:

Rit = i + t + 1Electionit + 2Electionit Interactionit + Interactionit + X0+ Rit1 + "it:

Interaction refers to the variable in the bottom row, which is standardized to have a mean of 0 and a standard deviation of 1. The plotted coecients can thus be interpreted as changes in macroprudential policy prior to elections when the change in the variable is one standard deviation above the mean. For comparison, I also plot the baseline estimate from Table 3 (column 3). The regressions also include one lag of the dependent variable and country year fixed eects. 95% confidence intervals are based on standard errors clustered by country.

41

Figure 4: Elections and Macroprudential Regulation during Credit Booms

0.12

0.08

0.04

0.00

−0.04

−0.08

−0.12

−0.16

−4

−3

−2

−1

0

1

2

3

4

Quarters since election

Notes: This figure plots changes in sectoral capital buers around elections during credit booms. More specifically, I plot the linear combination of the estimated coecients ˆ1h + ˆ2h of the following regression:

4

X

Rit = i + t + 1hElectionit + 2hElectionit Credit=GDPit + Credit=GDPit + X0+ "it:

h=4

Credit=GDP is standardized to have a mean of 0 and a standard deviation of 1. The plotted coecients can thus be interpreted as changes in macroprudential policy around elections when the change in private credit/GDP is one standard deviation above the mean. The regression also includes country year fixed eects. 95% confidence intervals are based on standard errors clustered by country.

42

Figure 5: Dierentiating between Types of Elections

0.02

0.00

−0.005

−0.02

−0.014

−0.04

−0.029

−0.035

−0.06

−0.053

−0.08

−0.10

Baseline

Close

Not

Regular

Irregular

estimate

elections

close

elections

elections

elections

Notes: This figure plots changes in sectoral capital buers in pre-election quarters depending on whether

ˆ

of the

elections are close or regular. I plot the linear combination of the estimated OLS coecients

following regression:

Rit = i + t + P re electionit + X0+ Rit1 + "it:

For comparison, I also plot the baseline estimate from Table 5 (column 1). The regressions also include one lag of the dependent variable. 95% confidence intervals are based on standard errors clustered by country.

43

Figure 6: Electoral Cycles, Political Institutions, and Opposition Power

0.02

0.00

−0.001

−0.007

−0.008

−0.011

−0.014

−0.02

−0.029

−0.04

Baseline

High

Low

No

Independent

Strong

estimate

voice

state

MoF

bank

opposition

and acc.

intervention

connections

regulators

Notes: This figure plots changes in sectoral capital buers in pre-election quarters depending on the level of political institutions, political connections of regulators, state intervention, and strength of the opposition. For the models 1, 2, 3, 5 and 6 (from the left), I plot the linear combination of the estimated OLS coecients ˆ1 + ˆ2 of the following regression:

Rit = i + t + 1P re electionit + 2P re electionit Interactionit + 3Interactionit + X0+ Rit1 + "it:

For model 4 I plot ˆ1, which captures the correlation with upcoming elections for countries where the central bank governor did not previously work at the Ministry of Finance. Interaction refers to the variable in the bottom row, which is standardized to have a mean of 0 and a standard deviation of 1. The plotted coef- ficients can thus be interpreted as changes in macroprudential policy prior to elections when the variable is one standard deviation above the mean. For comparison, I also plot the baseline estimate from Table 3 (column 2). The regressions also include one lag of the dependent variable. 95% confidence intervals are based on standard errors clustered by country.

44

Tables

Table 1: Descriptive Statistics

Observations

Mean

Median

Std. Dev.

Macroprudential policy indices

Sectoral capital buers

3248

0.011

0.000

0.186

Prudential regulation index

3248

0.056

0.000

0.390

Targeted macroprudential tools

Real estate capital buer

3248

0.006

0.000

0.121

Consumer credit capital buer

3248

0.002

0.000

0.058

Other sectoral capital buer

3248

0.004

0.000

0.093

Loan-to-value ratio cap

2986

0.012

0.000

0.158

Concentration limit

1827

0.015

0.000

0.129

Interbank exposure

1065

0.019

0.000

0.143

Reserve requirements (FC)

3248

0.010

0.000

0.258

Broader macroprudential tools

General capital requirements

3024

0.031

0.000

0.174

Reserve requirements (LC)

3248

-0.008

0.000

0.321

Financial sector variables

Bank capitalization (%)

3004

8.379

7.900

3.322

Lending concentration

3108

64.839

63.917

20.403

Cost to income ratio (%)

3176

58.677

57.657

15.323

Non-performing loans (%)

2964

5.337

3.200

5.842

Return on assets

3140

1.111

1.166

1.536

Z-score

3180

12.533

11.585

7.547

Foreign bank share (%)

3136

34.321

33.000

24.561

Macroeconomic variables

Government exp./GDP

2952

0.176

0.185

0.046

Money market rate

3149

5.136

3.820

6.468

Growth in CB reserves

3063

0.143

0.099

0.286

Real credit growth

2931

0.081

0.056

0.160

Real GDP growth

2948

0.032

0.030

0.047

Current account/GDP

2972

0.054

0.000

3.866

Trade/GDP

2988

0.892

0.739

0.535

Investment/GDP

2940

0.227

0.222

0.044

Consumption/GDP

2940

0.579

0.573

0.083

Inflation rate

3135

0.043

0.029

0.053

Log(FX)

3111

2.092

1.293

2.496

45

Table 2: Testing for Electoral Cycles in Other Variables

Notes: This table tests for electoral cycles in variables other than macroprudential regulation using panel regressions of the type Cit = i + t + P re electionit + "it, where Cit is one of the control variables in

0ˆ

vector X (shown in the left column). Each cell is the of an individual regression. 1 quarter refers to specifications where Pre-election is a dummy equal to 1 for the immediate pre-election quarter. Under 4 quarters, Pre-election is a vector of dummies for the four quarters prior to an election; I plot the linear combination of the estimated coecients. The dependent variable is standardized to have a mean of 0 and a standard deviation of 1. The sample is the estimation sample including all controls, as in columns 2 of Table 3. All models include country and year-quarter fixed eects. Standard errors are clustered by country, with ***, **, and * denoting statistical significance at the 1%, 5%, and 10% level, respectively.

Pre-election horizon:

1 quarter

4 quarters

ˆ

t-stat

ˆ

t-stat

Financial sector variables

Bank capitalization (%)

0.015

(0.698)

0.106

(1.548)

Lending concentration

-0.026

(-1.075)

-0.028

(-0.245)

Cost to income ratio (%)

-0.006

(-0.147)

-0.009

(-0.048)

Non-performing loans (%)

-0.028

(-0.683)

-0.071(-0.402)

Return on assets

-0.007

(-0.140)

0.096

(0.358)

Z-score

-0.004

(-0.171)

-0.007

(-0.081)

Foreign bank share (%)

-0.006

(-0.736)

-0.035

(-0.963)

Macroeconomic variables

Government exp./GDP

0.016

(0.596)

0.043

(0.574)

Money market rate

0.011

(0.691)

0.088

(0.642)

Growth in CB reserves

0.130

(1.501)

0.136

(0.439)

Real credit growth

-0.060(-1.023)

-0.302(-1.159)

Real GDP growth

0.033

(0.635)

0.006

(0.028)

Current account/GDP

0.043

(0.524)

0.181

(1.155)

Trade/GDP

0.009

(0.749)

0.026

(0.618)

Investment/GDP

0.021

(0.691)

0.241**

(2.083)

Consumption/GDP

-0.004(-0.148)

0.058

(1.376)

Inflation rate

0.025

(0.747)

0.240

(1.232)

Log(FX)

0.006

(1.406)

-0.010

(-0.406)

46

Table 3: Baseline Results - Elections and Macroprudential Regulation

Notes: This table shows coecients from estimating equation 1. The dependent variable is the change in sectoral capital buers. Pre-election is a dummy that is one for the quarter prior to an election. All estimations include one lag of the dependent variable as covariates and other controls as indicated. Note that the specification with country year dummies in column 3 does not require countries to have data on the annual financial sector controls, which explains the higher observation count. "Lagged controls" include four quarters of lags of the baseline controls. "Lead controls" include one quarter (or year) of leads. See text for a description of the control variables. Standard errors are clustered by coun- try, with ***, **, and * denoting statistical significance at the 1%, 5%, and 10% level, respectively.

(1)

(2)

(3)

(4)

(5)

(6)

Pre-election

-0.020**

-0.029**-0.041***-0.039**-0.036**-0.029**

(0.008)

(0.012)

(0.015)

(0.016)

(0.014)

(0.012)

Observations

3,422

2,409

2,640

2,409

2,251

2,026

R2

0.04

0.06

0.33

0.07

0.09

0.10

Dep. variable mean

0.011

0.012

0.012

0.012

0.012

0.013

Dep. variable SD

0.182

0.203

0.197

0.203

0.209

0.217

Country FE

Yes

Yes

-

-

Yes

Yes

Country Year FE

Yes

Country Election year FE

Yes

Time FE

Yes

Yes

Yes

Yes

Yes

Yes

Baseline controls

Yes

Yes

Yes

Yes

Yes

Lagged controls

Yes

Yes

Lead controls

Yes

47

Table 4: Results by Macroprudential Tool

Notes: This table shows coecients from estimating equation 1, where the dependent variable is a dummy for tightening or loosening the indicated macroprudential instrument. Each cell represents the results

from an individual regression. I only plot the estimated coe cient of the pre-election dummy . The

ˆ

dummy refers to the quarter immediately prior to an election except for LTV ratios, where it refers to the quarter two quarters before. All estimations include one lag of the dependent variable. In columns 2 and 4, I further include the vector of control variables described in the text. The coecient on loosened general capital requirements cannot be estimated because these are never loosened in the sample period (see Cerutti et al. (2017)). Standard errors are clustered by country, reported under the estimated coef- ficient, with ***, **, and * denoting statistical significance at the 1%, 5%, and 10% level, respectively.

Tightening

Loosening

Without

With

Without

With

controls

controls

controls

controls

(1)

(2)

(3)

(4)

Macroprudential policy indices

Sectoral capital buers

-0.015***

-0.019***

0.004

0.009

(0.003)

(0.005)

(0.006)

(0.009)

Prudential regulation index

-0.012

-0.015

0.028*

0.030

(0.019)

(0.025)

(0.016)

(0.020)

Targeted macroprudential tools

Real estate capital buer

-0.011***

-0.014***

0.000

0.003

(0.003)

(0.004)

(0.005)

(0.007)

Consumer credit capital buer

-0.002**

-0.002*

0.003

0.005

(0.001)

(0.001)

(0.005)

(0.007)

Other sectoral capital buer

-0.004**

-0.005*

-0.001

-0.001

(0.002)

(0.003)

(0.001)

(0.001)

Loan-to-value ratio

-0.002

-0.015***

0.001

0.002

(0.006)

(0.004)

(0.004)

(0.007)

Concentration limit

-0.007

-0.019**

0.007

0.010

(0.010)

(0.007)

(0.008)

(0.010)

Interbank exposure

-0.019**

-0.016

-0.000

-0.001

(0.008)

(0.011)

(0.001)

(0.003)

Reserve requirements (FC)

-0.015*

-0.009

-0.002

-0.005

(0.009)

(0.006)

(0.006)

(0.008)

Broader macroprudential tools

General capital requirements

0.003

0.005

-

-

(0.011)

(0.014)

Reserve requirements (LC)

-0.004

-0.005

0.014

0.015

(0.013)

(0.018)

(0.012)

(0.016)

48

Table 5: Electoral Cycles - Dierences across Types of Elections

Notes: This table shows coecients from estimating equation 1. The dependent variable is the change in sectoral capital buers. All estimations include one lag of the dependent variable as covariates and other controls as indicated. In column 2, I restrict the pre-election dummy to "reg- ular" elections, defined as those that were not held late or prematurely (while tolerating one quarter of dierence); column 3 uses the remaining "irregular" elections. In column 4, I restrict the sample to election periods that are relatively "close", where the outcome is uncertain; column 5 uses the relatively less close elections. Standard errors are clustered by country, with

***, **, and * denoting statistical significance at the 1%, 5%, and 10% level, respectively.

Election timing

Election outcome

Baseline

Regular

Irregular

Close

Not close

(1)

(2)

(3)

(4)

(5)

Pre-election

-0.029**

-0.035**

-0.014

-0.053**

-0.005

(0.012)

(0.016)

(0.009)

(0.024)

(0.011)

Observations

2,409

2,409

2,409

2,007

2,007

Elections

151

107

44

63

63

R2

0.062

0.062

0.061

0.072

0.070

Dep. variable mean

0.012

0.012

0.012

0.010

0.010

Country FE

Yes

Yes

Yes

Yes

Yes

Time FE

Yes

Yes

Yes

Yes

Yes

Controls

Yes

Yes

Yes

Yes

Yes

49

Table 6: Electoral Cycles and Procyclical Macroprudential Policy

Notes: This table shows coecients from estimating equation 1 using OLS. The dependent variable is the change in the sectoral capital buer index. Interaction refers to the variable measuring economic expansions or financial sector booms listed in the top row. The interaction variables are standardized to have a mean of 0 and a standard deviation of 1. All estimations include one lag of the dependent variable, country year fixed eects, time fixed eects, and the macroeconomic control variables as described in the text. Standard errors are clustered by coun- try, with ***, **, and * denoting statistical significance at the 1%, 5%, and 10% level, respectively.

GDP

GDP

House price

Bank

Credit/

growth

forecast

growth

ROE

GDP

(1)

(2)

(3)

(4)

(5)

Pre-election

-0.043***

-0.042***

-0.037**

-0.040***

-0.046***

Pre-election Interaction

(0.015)

(0.015)

(0.016)

(0.016)

(0.015)

-0.021**

-0.027**

-0.029***

-0.029***

-0.041***

(0.010)

(0.012)

(0.011)

(0.011)

(0.014)

Observations

2,638

2,640

2,147

2,554

2,645

R2

0.33

0.33

0.36

0.33

0.33

Dep. variable mean

0.012

0.012

0.011

0.012

0.012

Country Year FE

Yes

Yes

Yes

Yes

Yes

Time FE

Yes

Yes

Yes

Yes

Yes

Controls

Yes

Yes

Yes

Yes

Yes

50

Table 7: Do Regulatory Cycles Have Permanent Eects?

Notes: This table shows coecients from estimating equation 1 using OLS. The dependent variable is the change in the sector-specific capital buers index. P ost Election is a dummy variable equal to 1 for the two quarters after an election took place, and 0 otherwise. P re election + P ost election is the linear combination of the pre-election and post-election dummies. All estimations include one lag of the dependent variable and control variables as described in the text. Column 3 includes country year fixed eects that absorb the financial sector controls; the model has more observations because it only requires data on the quarterly macroeconomic variables. Standard errors are clustered by coun- try, with ***, **, and * denoting statistical significance at the 1%, 5%, and 10% level, respectively.

Only

Add

Add country

FE

controls

year FE

(1)

(2)

(3)

Pre-election

-0.019**

-0.029**

-0.042**

(0.008)

(0.012)

(0.016)

Post-election (3 quarters)

0.006

0.002

-0.003

(0.010)

(0.013)

(0.012)

Observations

3,422

2,409

2,640

R2

0.04

0.06

0.33

Dep. variable mean

0.011

0.012

0.012

Pre-election + Post-election

-0.012

-0.027

-0.045*

(0.013)

(0.019)

(0.024)

Country FE

Yes

Yes

Yes

Time FE

Yes

Yes

Yes

Controls

Yes

Yes

Country Year FE

Yes

51

Table 8: Elections and Macroprudential Regulation - Robustness

Notes: This table shows coecients from estimating equation 1, where the dependent variable is a dummy for tightening or loosening sectoral capital buers. Each cell under Tightening and Loosening represents an individual regression. I only plot the estimated coecient of the pre-election

ˆ

quarter dummy and the associated t-statistic. Unless otherwise indicated, all estimations include one lag of the dependent variable as well as country and year-quarter fixed eects. Note that the coecients on the tightening dummy cannot be estimated with logit because of perfect separation (they are never loosened prior to elections in the sample). Standard errors are clustered by coun- try, with ***, **, and * denoting statistical significance at the 1%, 5%, and 10% level, respectively.

Tightening

Loosening

ˆ

t-stat

ˆ

t-stat

Panel A: Model specification

No FE

-0.016***

(-4.81)

0.004

(0.70)

Only time FE

-0.015***

(-4.69)

0.004

(0.73)

AR(0)

-0.015***

(-4.42)

0.004

(0.66)

AR(4)

-0.015***

(-4.33)

0.004

(0.64)

Mean group estimator, no FE

-0.016***(-4.66)

0.003

(0.63)

Logit, no FE

-

0.601

(0.95)

Logit, only time FE

-

0.695

(0.89)

Logit, both FE

-

1.193

(1.16)

GMM, no FE

-0.021***

(-3.89)

0.004

(0.62)

Only keep election years

-0.025***

(-3.18)

0.002

(0.29)

Panel B: Sample selection

Only consensus democracies

-0.013***

(-3.81)

0.004

(0.64)

No military leaders

-0.015***

(-4.35)

0.004

(0.66)

Drop Africa

-0.015***

(-4.29)

0.004

(0.65)

Drop Asia

-0.011***

(-3.40)

0.005

(0.65)

Drop Americas

-0.016***

(-4.01)

-0.000(-0.01)

Drop Europe

-0.018**

(-2.32)

0.007

(0.85)

Drop Oceania

-0.016***

(-4.33)

0.004

(0.64)

Drop countries without changes

-0.036***

(-5.09)

0.018

(0.44)

Drop countries with most changes

-0.010***

(-3.81)

0.002

(0.34)

Pre-crisis only

-0.008***

(-2.68)

0.009

(0.87)

Post-crisis only

-0.020***

(-3.73)

-0.001

(-0.06)

Panel C: Additional controls

Only bank controls

-0.015***

(-4.08)

0.005

(0.70)

20 bank controls

-0.017***

(-4.20)

0.009

(0.98)

Only macro controls

-0.019***

(-4.19)

0.007

(0.90)

Factor controls

-0.019***

(-4.07)

0.010

(1.01)

Country Year FE

-0.019***

(-2.92)

0.008

(1.14)

Country Half-Year FE

-0.036***

(-2.82)

0.010

(1.62)

Country Quarter FE

-0.017***

(-3.66)

0.006

(0.92)

Regulation Time FE

-0.015***

(-2.87)

0.004

(0.69)

Region Time FE

-0.013**

(-2.55)

-0.001(-0.09)

Development Time FE

-0.013***

(-3.31)

0.005

(0.84)

52

Table 9: Political Institutions, Opposition Power, and Electoral Cycles

Notes: This table shows coecients from estimating equation 1. The dependent variable is the change in sectoral capital buers. All estimations include one lag of the dependent variable as covariates and other controls as indicated. Voice and accountability comes from the World Bank's World Governance Indicators (WGI). State intervention is the index on the state ownership of assets from the Fraser Institute. CB governor connections at MoF is a dummy equal to 1 if the central bank's governor worked at the Ministry of Finance prior to his tenure. Politically independent bank supervision is a dummy equal to one for countries where the bank supervisors are relatively independent from political influence by the government from Barth et al. (2013). Unified opposition measures the concentration of the opposition party in parliament, based on data from Beck et al. (2001) (updated in Cruz et al. (2018)). Standard errors are clustered by country, with ***, **, and * denoting statistical significance at the 1%, 5%, and 10% level, respectively.

CB governor

Politically

Voice and

State

connections

independent

Unified

accountability

intervention

at MoF

bank supervision

opposition

(1)

(2)

(3)

(4)

(5)

Pre-election

-0.024**

-0.030**

-0.008

-0.035**

-0.030**

Pre-election Interaction

(0.010)

(0.012)

(0.009)

(0.014)

(0.013)

0.012**

0.023**

-0.044**

0.034**

0.015*

(0.006)

(0.010)

(0.021)

(0.016)

(0.008)

Observations

2,292

2,409

2,407

2,269

2,354

R2

0.06

0.06

0.06

0.06

0.07

Dep. variable mean

0.012

0.012

0.011

0.013

0.011

Country FE

Yes

Yes

Yes

Yes

Yes

Time FE

Yes

Yes

Yes

Yes

Yes

Controls

Yes

Yes

Yes

Yes

Yes

53

Table 10: Election Cycles, Politically Connected Banks, and Lobbying

Notes: This table shows coecients from estimating equation 1 using OLS. The dependent variable is the change in the sector-specific capital buers index. Interaction refers to the proxy for political connections or lobbying power of the financial sector listed in the top row. The interaction variables are standardized to have a mean of 0 and a standard deviation of 1. All estimations include one lag of the dependent variable and the baseline control variables as described in the text. Campaign fin. lim. in column 2 is an index of legal restrictions on campaign financing constructed from the IDEA Political Finance Database. Connected firms in column 3 is the share of firms with political connections by market capitalization from Faccio (2006). Connected banks in column 4 is the share of banks with at least one former politician on the board of directors from Braun & Raddatz (2010). Connected CB governor is a dummy for countries where the central bank governor has previous work experience in the financial sec- tor. The regressions also include the interaction measures by themselves in columns 1 and 5 (unreported); they are absorbed by the country fixed eects in the other columns. Standard errors are clustered by country, with ***, **, and * denoting statistical significance at the 1%, 5%, and 10% level, respectively.

Bank

Campaign

Connected

Connected

Connected

concentration

fin. lim.

firms

banks

CB governor

(1)

(2)

(3)

(4)

(5)

Pre-election

-0.030**

-0.029**

-0.035**

-0.029**

-0.035*

Pre-election Interaction

(0.013)

(0.012)

(0.014)

(0.013)

(0.019)

-0.007

0.002

0.006

-0.001

0.014

(0.010)

(0.010)

(0.008)

(0.007)

(0.017)

Observations

2,409

2,409

1,974

2,378

2,407

R2

0.06

0.06

0.06

0.06

0.06

Dep. variable mean

0.012

0.012

0.015

0.011

0.011

Country FE

Yes

Yes

Yes

Yes

Yes

Time FE

Yes

Yes

Yes

Yes

Yes

Controls

Yes

Yes

Yes

Yes

Yes

54

Table 11: The Electoral Cycle Does Not Vary with Uncertainty

Notes: This table shows coecients from estimating equation 1. The dependent variable is the change

in sectoral capital buers. Uncertainty refers to the measure of uncertainty listed in the top row: the Economic Policy Index (EPU) in column 1; World Uncertainty Index (WUI) in column 2; stock market volatility in column 3; and the Chicago Board Options Exchange implied volatility index (VIX) in column 4. Note that the VIX only varies by year, not by country. The uncertainty variables are standardized to have a mean of 0 and a standard deviation of 1. The regressions also include the uncertainty measures by themselves (unreported). All estimations include one lag of the dependent variable as covariates and the baseline control variables as described in the text. Standard errors are clustered by country, with ***, **, and * denoting statistical significance at the 1%, 5%, and 10% level, respectively.

Stock price

Log(EPU)

Log(WUI)

volatility

Log(VIX)

(1)

(2)

(3)

(4)

Pre-election

-0.033*

-0.035**

-0.030**

-0.029**

Pre-election Uncertainty

(0.016)

(0.016)

(0.013)

(0.012)

0.000

0.015

0.006

0.002

(0.014)

(0.015)

(0.004)

(0.009)

Observations

1,720

1,811

2,349

2,409

R2

0.07

0.08

0.06

0.06

Dep. variable mean

0.006

0.015

0.012

0.012

Country FE

Yes

Yes

Yes

Yes

Time FE

Yes

Yes

Yes

Yes

Controls

Yes

Yes

Yes

Yes

55

56

Table 12: Institutional Frameworks, Elections, and Macroprudential Policy

Notes: This table shows coecients from estimating regressions of the type in equation 1. The dependent variable is the change in sectoral capital buers. Financial stability committee (advisory) is a dummy variable for countries where a committee on macropru- dential policy decisions exists but the committee does not have decision making powers (Edge & Liang, 2017). Financial stability committee (decides) is a dummy for countries where it does. Macropru. decided by CB indicates whether the central bank has more than a 50% share in macroprudential policy decisions as classified by Cerutti et al. (2015). C-M and D-E refer to data on central bank independence and transparency from Crowe & Meade (2007) and Dincer & Eichengreen (2014), respectively. The sample in columns 1 through 5 excludes the Eurozone countries, where these measures refer to the European Central Bank, which is not in charge of macroprudential policy. It is also limited to countries where the central bank decides on policy. The continuous interaction variables are standardized to have a mean of 0 and a standard deviation of 1. All estimations include one lag of the dependent variable, country and year-quarter fixed eects, and the baseline control variables as described in the text. Standard errors are clustered by country, with ***, **, and * denoting statistical significance at the 1%, 5%, and 10% level, respectively.

If central bank decides macroprudential policy...

Macropru.

De jure CB independence

CB transparency

Financial stability committee

decided

Crowe-

Dincer-

Crowe-

Dincer-

Advisory

Decides

by CB

Meade

Eichengreen

Meade

Eichengreen

(1)

(2)

(3)

(4)

(5)

(6)

(7)

Pre-election

-0.025

-0.036**

-0.023

-0.055***

-0.035*

-0.123

-0.046*

Pre-election Interaction

(0.016)

(0.015)

(0.014)

(0.015)

(0.016)

(0.064)

(0.021)

-0.008

0.040**

-0.006

0.020

0.005

-0.016

-0.001

(0.020)

(0.019)

(0.016)

(0.020)

(0.025)

(0.028)

(0.017)

Observations

2,378

2,378

2,027

527

445

289

552

R2

0.06

0.06

0.06

0.17

0.26

0.29

0.16

Dep. variable mean

0.011

0.011

0.013

0.034

0.031

0.028

0.031

Country FE

Yes

Yes

Yes

Yes

Yes

Yes

Yes

Time FE

Yes

Yes

Yes

Yes

Yes

Yes

Yes

Controls

Yes

Yes

Yes

Yes

Yes

Yes

Yes

Appendix (For Online Publication)

Table A1: Descriptive Statistics of Additional Variables

Observations

Mean

Median

Std. Dev.

Election timing

Pre-election

3248

0.065

0.000

0.247

Pre-election (regular)

3248

0.048

0.000

0.213

Pre-election (irregular)

3248

0.018

0.000

0.131

Pre-election (close)

2564

0.032

0.000

0.177

Pre-election (not close)

2564

0.034

0.000

0.181

Post-election (2 quarters)

3248

0.128

0.000

0.334

Economic expansions and credit booms

GDP forecast

3224

3.287

3.279

1.863

Real house price growth

2408

2.166

1.808

9.191

Banking sector ROE

3140

13.311

14.873

13.105

Credit/GDP growth

2880

0.037

0.029

0.149

Political characteristics

Voice and accountability

3016

0.745

0.929

0.677

State interventionism

3136

7.573

7.562

1.322

CB governor connections at MoF

3238

0.416

0.000

0.493

Pol. ind. bank regulators

2912

0.269

0.000

0.444

Unified opposition

3168

0.523

0.489

0.236

Political connections and lobbying

Campaign finance limits

3248

0.131

0.140

0.045

Connected firms

2352

0.083

0.016

0.159

Connected banks

3192

0.632

0.000

1.020

Connected CB governor

3238

0.373

0.000

0.484

Uncertainty

Log(EPU)

2160

4.737

4.719

0.413

Log(WUI)

2346

-1.677

-1.649

0.678

Stock price volatility

2988

22.299

20.155

12.189

Log(VIX)

3248

2.965

2.943

0.355

57

58

Table A2: Variable Description and Sources (1/3)

Description

Source

Financial Sector

Bank capitalization (%)

Ratio of bank capital and reserves to total assets. Capital

World Bank GFD

includes tier 1 capital and total regulatory capital.

Lending concentration

The asset market share of a country's three largest banks.

World Bank GFD

Cost to income ratio (%)

Banks' costs divided by their income.

World Bank GFD

Non-performing loans (%)

The ratio of a country's non-performing to total outstand-

World Bank GFD

ing loans.

ROA

The banking system's pre-tax return on assets.

World Bank GFD

Z-score

The Z-score captures the probability of default of a coun-

World Bank GFD

try's banking system by comparing its buer (capitaliza-

tion and returns) with the volatility of those returns.

Foreign bank share (%)

Percentage of the total banking assets that are held by for-

World Bank GFD

eign banks.

Macroeconomic Variables

Government exp./GDP

Government expenditure scaled over GDP.

IMF, OECD

Money market rate

A typical short-term money market interest rate.

IMF, OECD

Growth in central bank reserves

The year-on-year growth of central bank reserves (or the

IMF, OECD

monetary base, depending on availability), a measure of

monetary policy.

Real credit growth

The inflation-adjustedyear-on-year growth in financial

IMF

sector claims on the private sector.

Real GDP growth

Year-on-year growth in gross domestic product, adjusted

IMF, OECD

for inflation.

Current account/GDP

The ratio of the current account to GDP.

IMF, OECD

Total trade/GDP

The sum of total exports and imports, scaled over GDP.

IMF, OECD

Investment/GDP

The ratio of gross fixed capital formation to GDP.

IMF, OECD

Consumption/GDP

The ratio of private household consumption to GDP.

IMF, OECD

Inflation rate

The year-on-year growth in a country's consumer price in-

IMF, OECD

dex.

Exchange rate (US$)

A country's exchange rate vis-à-vis the US dollar.

IMF, OECD

Central bank rate

The central bank's ocial policy rate or the market rate

IMF, BIS, National central banks

explicitly targeted by the central bank.

Economic expansions and credit booms

GDP forecast

The World Bank's GDP forecast for the current year.

World Bank

Real house price growth

The year-on-year real growth in house prices.

BIS, OECD

59

Table A3: Variable Description and Sources (2/3)

Description

Source

Elections

Pre-election

Dummy variable equal to 1 in quarters prior to a

Various (see text).

general election.

Pre-election (regular)

Dummy variable equal to 1 in quarters prior to

Author's calculation.

regular elections, defined as those taking place

within a quarter after the anticipated date based

on a country's term limit for chief executives or

regular practice.

Pre-election (close)

Dummy variable equal to 1 in quarters prior to

Author's calculation.

close elections, defined as those where the vote

share dierence between the election winner and

the runner-up is below the median across elec-

tions in the sample.

Political characteristics

Voice and accountability

Measure of voice and accountability.

World Governance Indicators

State intervention

Index of the degree of state ownership of assets.

Fraser Institute

CB governor connections at MoF

Dummy for whether the central bank governor

Various, Mishra & Reshef (2019)

previously worked at the Ministry of Finance.

Politically independent bank supervision

Dummy for countries where bank supervisors are

Barth et al. (2013)

relatively more independent from the govern-

ment (first survey round).

Unified opposition

The Herfindahl index of opposition parties in

Cruz et al. (2018)

parliament. Higher values indicate a more uni-

fied opposition.

Connectedness and lobbying

Connected firms

The share of politically connected firms (by mar-

Faccio (2006)

ket capitalization).

Connected banks

The share of banks with at least one former politi-

Braun & Raddatz (2008)

cian on its board.

Connected CB governor

Dummy for whether the central bank governor

Various, Mishra & Reshef (2019)

previously worked at a private financial institu-

tion.

Campaign finance limits

An index of legal limits on campaign financing.

IDEA Political Finance Database

Constructed as sum of bans and limits on private

income; regulations of spending; and reporting,

oversight and sanctions in a given country.

60

Table A4: Variable Description and Sources (3/3)

Description

Source

Uncertainty measures

Economic Policy Uncertainty

The index of economic policy uncertainty for all

Baker et al. (2016)

countries available at . I re-scale all country-level in-

dices to 1 in 2008q1. For the EU countries that do

not have data, I assign the aggregate European index.

For Taiwan, I use the Chinese index.

World Uncertainty Index

The index of world uncertainty, available on Nicholas

Ahir et al. (2018).

Bloom's website.

Stock price volatility

The average of the 360-day volatility of the national

World Bank GFD

stock market index.

VIX

Expected stock market volatility implied by S&P 500

St. Louis Fed (FRED)

index options as calculated by the Chicago Board Op-

tions Exchange (CBOE)

Macroprudential institutions

CBI (Dincer & Eichengreen)

Measure of central bank independence covering 2000

Dincer & Eichengreen (2014)

to 2010. I extend the series to 2014 using the growth

rates of the data in Garriga (2016) (results are un-

changed without this adjustment).

CBI (Crowe & Meade)

A measure of central bank independence in 2003.

Crowe & Meade (2007)

CB transparency (Dincer & Eichengreen)

Measure of central bank transparency covering 2000

Dincer & Eichengreen (2014)

to 2010. I extend the series to 2014 by assuming

no change between 2010 and 2014 (results are un-

changed without this adjustment).

CB transparency (Crowe & Meade)

Measure of central bank transparency in 2003.

Crowe & Meade (2007)

Financial stability committee (advisory)

Dummy variable equal to 1 if a country has a macro-

Edge & Liang (2017)

prudential committee consisting of multiple mem-

bers but no decision making powers, and 0 otherwise.

Financial stability committee (power)

Dummy variable equal to 1 if a country has a macro-

Edge & Liang (2017)

prudential committee that has decision making pow-

ers over tools, and 0 otherwise.

Central bank majority powers

Dummy variable equal to 1 if a country's national

Cerutti et al. (2015)

central bank has more than 50% decision share over

macroprudential tools.

Table A5: Correlation Matrix of Macroprudential Tools

Notes:

This

table

plots

pairwise

Pearson correlation

coecients

of

the prudential

tools

from Cerutti et

al.

(2017).

***,

**,

and

* denote statistical significance at

the

1%,

5%,

and 10% level, respectively.

(1)

(2)

(3)

(4)

(5)

(6)

(7)

(8)

(9)

(10)

(11)

(1)

Macroprudential regulation index

1

(2)

Sector-specific capital buer

0.3110*

1

(3)

Real estate capital buer

0.2811*

0.7854*

1

(4)

Consumer credit capital buer

0.1286*

0.5338*

0.2144*

1

(5)

Other capital buer

0.1743*

0.6402*

0.1311*

0.1672*

1

(6)

General capital requirements

0.3565*

-0.0101

0.0057

-0.0046

-0.0253

1

(7)

Concentration limit

0.2515*

-0.0072

-0.0068

-0.0043

-0.0028

0.0054

1

(8)

Interbank exposure

0.3317*

0.0648

0.0418

0.0059

0.0885*

0.0463

0.1575*

1

(9)

Loan-to-value ratio

0.5839*

0.0122

0.0169

-0.0021

-0.0052

0.0084

0.0918

-0.0056

1

(10)

Reserve requirements (FC)

0.4296*

0.0104

0.0077

0.0194

-0.0013

-0.0061

-0.0176

0.0143

-0.0059

1

(11)

Reserve requirements (LC)

0.5970*

0.0860*

0.0547*

0.0487*

0.0699*

-0.0564*

-0.0217

0.0083

0.0047

0.3509*

1

61

Table A6: Tightening and Loosening Episodes, by Pre-Election Quarter

Notes:

This

table plots

the

number

of tightening and

loosening episodes

for

all

prudential tools in

the dataset

of Cerutti et

al.

(2017)

that overlap with the election

data

criteria

described

above.

Tightening episodes

Loosening episodes

Pre-election

Other

Pre-election

Other

Total

quarters

quarters

Total

quarters

quarters

Macroprudential policy indices

Sector-specific capital buers

51

0

51

16

2

14

Macroprudential regulation index

329

22

307

166

15

151

62

Targeted macroprudential tools

Real estate capital buer

35

0

35

13

1

12

Consumer credit capital buer

8

0

8

2

1

1

Other capital buer

15

0

15

5

0

5

Loan-to-value ratio

64

10

54

26

2

24

Concentration limit

29

1

28

1

1

0

Interbank exposure

24

0

24

1

0

1

Reserve requirements (FC)

84

3

81

49

2

47

Broader macroprudential tools

General capital requirement

88

7

81

0

0

0

Reserve requirements (LC)

106

7

99

147

11

136

Table A7: Changes to Regulation and Number of Elections, by Country

Tightening

Loosening

Type of

Number of

Country

SSCB

Index

SSCB

Index

election

elections

Argentina

0

9

2

13

Presidential

3

Australia

1

5

1

1

Legislative

5

Austria

0

2

0

1

Legislative

4

Belgium

0

1

0

0

Legislative

4

Brazil

5

15

4

8

Presidential

4

Bulgaria

2

11

1

5

Legislative

5

Canada

0

6

0

2

Legislative

5

Chile

0

1

0

2

Presidential

3

Colombia

0

3

0

2

Presidential

4

Croatia

2

11

0

5

Legislative

3

Czech Rep.

0

2

0

2

Legislative

4

Denmark

0

4

0

2

Legislative

4

Estonia

1

5

2

5

Legislative

4

Finland

0

2

0

0

Legislative

3

France

0

6

0

1

Presidential

3

Germany

0

3

0

0

Legislative

4

Greece

0

1

0

1

Legislative

5

Hungary

0

3

0

6

Legislative

4

Iceland

0

3

0

6

Legislative

4

India

6

17

2

9

Legislative

3

Indonesia

0

9

0

1

Presidential

3

Ireland

2

4

0

0

Legislative

3

Israel

4

8

0

0

Legislative

5

Italy

0

2

0

0

Legislative

4

Japan

0

2

0

0

Legislative

5

Latvia

0

9

3

9

Legislative

5

Lebanon

0

4

0

2

Legislative

4

63

TableA7: Changes to Regulation and Number of Elections, by Country (continued)

Tightening

Loosening

Type of

Number of

Country

SSCB

Index

SSCB

Index

election

elections

Lithuania

0

3

0

3

Legislative

4

Malaysia

2

7

0

2

Legislative

3

Malta

0

2

0

3

Legislative

3

Mexico

0

3

0

0

Presidential

3

Mongolia

0

4

0

1

Legislative

4

Netherlands

0

6

0

0

Legislative

5

New Zealand

0

2

0

0

Legislative

5

Nigeria

1

6

0

2

Presidential

4

Norway

0

4

2

2

Legislative

4

Peru

1

15

0

6

Presidential

3

Philippines

1

14

0

6

Presidential

2

Poland

3

6

0

2

Legislative

4

Portugal

0

3

0

1

Legislative

4

Romania

0

9

0

8

Legislative

4

Russia

1

13

0

5

Presidential

3

Serbia

2

15

1

11

Legislative

6

Singapore

0

10

0

0

Legislative

3

Slovakia

0

3

0

5

Legislative

4

Slovenia

1

3

0

1

Legislative

5

South Africa

0

2

0

0

Legislative

3

South Korea

1

10

0

4

Presidential

3

Spain

1

3

0

3

Legislative

3

Sweden

2

7

0

0

Legislative

4

Switzerland

3

5

0

0

Legislative

3

Taiwan

0

8

0

4

Presidential

3

Thailand

4

7

0

3

Legislative

6

Turkey

3

16

0

5

Legislative

3

64

TableA7: Changes to Regulation and Number of Elections, by Country (continued)

Tightening

Loosening

Type of

Number of

Country

SSCB

Index

SSCB

Index

election

elections

Ukraine

0

4

0

8

Presidential

3

United Kingdom

0

3

0

0

Legislative

3

United States

0

2

0

0

Presidential

4

Uruguay

1

5

0

3

Legislative

3

Total

50

348

18

171

221

65

Table A8: List of Elections in Main Estimation Sample

Country

Quarter

Country

Quarter

Country

Quarter

Country

Quarter

Argentina

2003q2

France

2007q2

Lithuania

2008q4

Serbia

2007q1

Argentina

2007q4

France

2012q2

Lithuania

2012q4

Serbia

2008q2

Argentina

2011q4

Germany

2002q3

Malaysia

2004q1

Serbia

2012q2

Australia

2001q4

Germany

2005q3

Malaysia

2008q1

Serbia

2014q1

Australia

2004q4

Germany

2009q3

Malaysia

2013q2

Singapore

2001q4

Australia

2007q4

Germany

2013q3

Malta

2003q2

Singapore

2006q2

Australia

2010q3

Greece

2000q2

Malta

2008q1

Singapore

2011q2

Australia

2013q3

Greece

2004q1

Malta

2013q1

Slovak Republic

2002q3

Austria

2002q4

Greece

2007q3

Mexico

2000q3

Slovak Republic

2006q2

Austria

2006q4

Greece

2009q4

Mexico

2006q3

Slovak Republic

2010q2

Austria

2008q3

Greece

2012q2

Mexico

2012q3

Slovak Republic

2012q1

Austria

2013q3

Hungary

2002q2

Mongolia

2001q2

Slovenia

2000q4

Belgium

2003q2

Hungary

2006q2

Mongolia

2005q2

Slovenia

2004q4

Belgium

2007q2

Hungary

2010q2

Mongolia

2009q2

Slovenia

2008q3

Belgium

2010q2

Hungary

2014q2

Mongolia

2013q2

Slovenia

2011q4

Belgium

2014q2

Iceland

2003q2

Netherlands

2002q2

Slovenia

2014q3

Brazil

2002q4

Iceland

2007q2

Netherlands

2003q1

South Africa

2004q2

Brazil

2006q4

Iceland

2009q2

Netherlands

2006q4

South Africa

2009q2

Brazil

2010q4

Iceland

2013q2

Netherlands

2010q2

South Africa

2014q2

Brazil

2014q4

India

2004q1

Netherlands

2012q3

Spain

2000q1

Bulgaria

2001q2

India

2009q2

New Zealand

2002q3

Spain

2004q1

Bulgaria

2005q2

India

2014q2

New Zealand

2005q3

Spain

2008q1

Bulgaria

2009q3

Indonesia

2004q3

New Zealand

2008q4

Spain

2011q4

Bulgaria

2013q2

Indonesia

2009q3

New Zealand

2011q4

Sweden

2002q3

Bulgaria

2014q4

Indonesia

2014q3

New Zealand

2014q3

Sweden

2006q3

Canada

2000q4

Ireland

2002q2

Nigeria

2003q2

Sweden

2010q3

Canada

2004q2

Ireland

2007q2

Nigeria

2007q2

Sweden

2014q3

Canada

2006q1

Ireland

2011q1

Nigeria

2011q2

Switzerland

2003q4

Canada

2008q4

Israel

2003q1

Norway

2001q3

Switzerland

2007q4

Canada

2011q2

Israel

2006q1

Norway

2005q3

Switzerland

2011q4

Chile

2005q4

Israel

2009q1

Norway

2009q3

Taiwan

2000q1

Chile

2009q4

Israel

2013q1

Norway

2013q3

Taiwan

2004q1

Chile

2013q4

Italy

2001q2

Peru

2000q2

Taiwan

2008q1

Colombia

2002q2

Italy

2006q2

Peru

2001q2

Taiwan

2012q1

Colombia

2006q2

Italy

2008q2

Peru

2006q2

Thailand

2001q1

Colombia

2010q2

Italy

2013q1

Peru

2011q2

Thailand

2005q1

Colombia

2014q2

Japan

2000q2

Philippines

2004q2

Thailand

2006q1

Croatia

2000q1

Japan

2003q4

Philippines

2010q2

Thailand

2007q4

Croatia

2003q4

Japan

2005q3

Poland

2001q3

Thailand

2011q3

Croatia

2007q4

Japan

2009q3

Poland

2005q3

Thailand

2014q1

Croatia

2011q4

Japan

2012q4

Poland

2007q4

Turkey

2002q4

Czech Republic

2002q2

Japan

2014q4

Poland

2011q4

Turkey

2007q3

Czech Republic

2006q2

South Korea

2002q4

Portugal

2002q1

Turkey

2011q2

Czech Republic

2010q2

South Korea

2007q4

Portugal

2005q1

Ukraine

2004q4

Czech Republic

2013q4

South Korea

2012q4

Portugal

2009q3

Ukraine

2010q1

Denmark

2001q4

Latvia

2002q4

Portugal

2011q2

Ukraine

2014q4

Denmark

2005q1

Latvia

2006q4

Romania

2000q4

United Kingdom

2001q3

Denmark

2007q4

Latvia

2010q4

Romania

2004q4

United Kingdom

2005q2

Denmark

2011q3

Latvia

2011q3

Romania

2008q4

United Kingdom

2010q2

Estonia

2003q1

Latvia

2014q4

Romania

2012q4

United States

2000q4

Estonia

2007q1

Lebanon

2000q3

Russian Federation

2000q1

United States

2004q4

Estonia

2011q1

Lebanon

2005q2

Russian Federation

2004q1

United States

2008q4

Finland

2003q1

Lebanon

2009q2

Russian Federation

2008q1

United States

2012q4

Finland

2007q1

Lebanon

2010q2

Russian Federation

2012q1

Uruguay

2004q4

Finland

2011q2

Lithuania

2000q4

Serbia

2000q4

Uruguay

2009q4

France

2002q2

Lithuania

2004q4

Serbia

2003q4

Uruguay

2014q4

66

Table A9: Cross Tabulation of Close and Not Close Elections

Notes:

This table

shows

the

proportion

of

elections

that

are close.

Elections are de-

fined

as "close"

if the

winner's margin

of

victory

is

below

the

sample median.

Pre-election quarter Other quarters

Total

Not close

88

2,546

2,634

Close

88

0

161

Total

176

2,546

2,722

Table A10: Cross Tabulation of Regular and Irregular Elections

Notes: This table shows the proportion of elections that are regular. Elections are defined as "regular" if they are held within the time frame specified in a country's constitution or by legislative practice.

Pre-election quarter

Other quarters

Total

Irregular

60

3,201

3,261

Regular

161

0

161

Total

221

3,201

3,422

67

Table A11: Testing for Electoral Cycles in Other Variables (First Dierences)

Notes: This table tests for electoral cycles in variables other than macroprudential regulation using panel regressions of the type Cit = i + t + P re electionit + "it, where Cit is the first dierence of the control

0ˆ

variables in vector X (shown in the left column). Each cell is the of an individual regression. 1 quarter refers to specifications where Pre-election is a dummy equal to 1 for the immediate pre-election quarter. Under 4 quarters, Pre-election is a vector of dummies for the four quarters prior to an election; I plot the linear combination of the estimated coecients. The dependent variable is standardized to have a mean of 0 and a standard deviation of 1. The sample is the estimation sample including all controls, as in columns 2 of Table 3. All models include country and year-quarter fixed eects. Standard errors are clustered by country, with ***, **, and * denoting statistical significance at the 1%, 5%, and 10% level, respectively.

Pre-election horizon:

1 quarter

4 quarters

ˆ

t-stat

ˆ

t-stat

Financial sector variables

Bank capitalization (%)

-0.035

(-0.472)

0.594**

(2.203)

Lending concentration

-0.029

(-0.340)

0.070

(0.244)

Cost to income ratio (%)

-0.011

(-0.123)

-0.296

(-0.809)

Non-performing loans (%)

-0.016

(-0.200)

-0.172(-0.576)

Return on assets

-0.060

(-0.572)

0.246

(0.548)

Z-score

-0.080(-1.020)

-0.406

(-1.323)

Foreign bank share (%)

0.015

(0.322)

-0.057

(-0.197)

Macroeconomic variables

Government exp./GDP

-0.053(-0.620)

0.049

(0.672)

Money market rate

0.082*

(1.744)

-0.138(-1.076)

Growth in CB reserves

0.117

(1.052)

0.351

(1.577)

Real credit growth

-0.125(-0.563)

-0.332(-1.024)

Real GDP growth

0.155*

(1.900)

0.152

(0.601)

Current account/GDP

0.013

(0.158)

0.086

(1.141)

Trade/GDP

0.146

(1.441)

0.046

(0.457)

Investment/GDP

-0.043

(-0.420)

0.052

(0.425)

Consumption/GDP

-0.006

(-0.052)

-0.051

(-0.537)

Inflation rate

-0.019(-0.328)

-0.029(-0.131)

Log(FX)

0.060

(1.386)

0.145

(0.925)

68

Table A12: Variable Means, by Pre-Election Quarter

Pre-election

Other

Mean

t-test

quarter

quarters

Dierence

(p-value)

Macroprudential policy indices

Sectoral capital buers

-0.014

0.014

0.028

0.009

Prudential regulation index

0.034

0.061

0.027

0.441

Targeted macroprudential tools

Real estate capital buer

-0.007

0.009

0.016

0.032

Consumer credit capital buer

-0.007

0.002

0.009

0.214

Other sectoral capital buer

0.000

0.003

0.003

0.144

Loan-to-value ratio cap

0.028

0.010

-0.019

0.287

Concentration limit

-0.011

0.018

0.029

0.015

Interbank exposure

0.000

0.018

0.018

0.000

Reserve requirements (FC)

0.000

0.006

0.006

0.751

Broader macroprudential tools

General capital requirements

0.041

0.030

-0.011

0.514

Reserve requirements (LC)

-0.014

-0.006

0.007

0.769

Financial sector variables

Bank capitalization (%)

8.196

8.261

0.066

0.825

Lending concentration

64.395

64.716

0.321

0.851

Cost to income ratio (%)

58.924

58.564

-0.360

0.752

Non-performing loans (%)

4.891

4.968

0.077

0.868

Return on assets

1.065

1.149

0.084

0.437

Z-score

12.258

12.230

-0.028

0.959

Foreign bank share (%)

33.762

34.531

0.769

0.706

Macroeconomic variables

Government exp./GDP

0.180

0.174

-0.006

0.138

Money market rate

4.311

4.370

0.059

0.894

Growth in CB reserves

0.165

0.129

-0.035

0.214

Real credit growth

0.063

0.076

0.013

0.242

Real GDP growth

0.032

0.032

-0.000

0.947

Current account/GDP

0.144

0.034

-0.110

0.504

Trade/GDP

0.874

0.880

0.007

0.874

Investment/GDP

0.227

0.228

0.001

0.787

Consumption/GDP

0.576

0.577

0.001

0.927

Inflation rate

0.037

0.038

0.000

0.931

Log(FX)

1.816

1.863

0.046

0.815

69

Table A13: The Electoral Cycles Does Not Vary With Changes in Uncertainty

Notes: This table shows coecients from estimating equation 1. The dependent variable is the change in sector-specific capital buers. Uncertainty refers to the change in the measure of uncertainty listed in the top row: the Economic Policy Index in column 1; World Uncertainty Index in column 2; stock market volatility in column 3; and the Chicago Board Options Exchange implied volatility index (VIX) in column 4. Note that the VIX only varies by year, not by country. The uncertainty variables are standardized to have a mean of 0 and a standard deviation of 1. The regressions also include the uncertainty measures themselves (unreported). All estimations include one lag of the dependent variable as covariates and the baseline control variables as described in the text. Standard errors are clustered by country, with ***, **, and * denoting statistical significance at the 1%, 5%, and 10% level, respectively.

Stock price

Log(EPU)

Log(WUI)

volatility

Log(VIX)

(1)

(2)

(3)

(4)

Pre-election

-0.032**

-0.037**

-0.031**

-0.029**

Pre-election Uncertainty

(0.015)

(0.015)

(0.013)

(0.012)

-0.003

-0.002

-0.005

-0.003

(0.017)

(0.007)

(0.007)

(0.008)

Observations

1,717

1,515

2,319

2,409

R2

0.07

0.09

0.07

0.06

Dep. variable mean

0.006

0.015

0.012

0.012

Country FE

Yes

Yes

Yes

Yes

Time FE

Yes

Yes

Yes

Yes

Controls

Yes

Yes

Yes

Yes

70

Table A14: Central Bank Independence, Elections, and Macroprudential Policy

Notes: This table shows coecients from estimating regressions of the type in equation 1. The dependent variable is the change in sectoral capital buers. In Panel B, the sample is restricted to countries where the central bank has more than a 50% share in macroprudential policy decisions as classified by Cerutti et al. (2015). Crowe-Meade and Dincer-Eichengreen refer to data on central bank independence and transparency from Crowe & Meade (2007) and Dincer & Eichengreen (2014), respectively. Garriga is the central bank independence measure from Garriga (2016). The sample excludes the Eurozone coun- tries, where these measures refer to the European Central Bank, which is not in charge of macropru- dential policy. The continuous interaction variables are standardized to have a mean of 0 and a standard deviation of 1. All estimations include one lag of the dependent variable, country and year-quarter fixed eects, and the baseline control variables as described in the text. Standard errors are clustered by country, with ***, **, and * denoting statistical significance at the 1%, 5%, and 10% level, respectively.

De jure CB independence

CB transparency

Crowe-

Dincer-

Garriga

Crowe-

Dincer-

Meade

Eichengreen

(2016)

Meade

Eichengreen

(1)

(2)

(3)

(4)

(5)

Panel A: Full sample

Pre-election

-0.039**

-0.026*

-0.036***

-0.050*

-0.038**

Pre-election Interaction

(0.015)

(0.013)

(0.013)

(0.025)

(0.016)

0.016

0.012

0.033

0.001

0.012

(0.013)

(0.017)

(0.022)

(0.014)

(0.010)

Observations

1,827

1,628

1,883

1,166

1,852

Panel B: Countries where central bank has majority decision making power

Pre-election

-0.055***

-0.035*

-0.047***

-0.123

-0.046*

Pre-election Interaction

(0.015)

(0.016)

(0.014)

(0.064)

(0.021)

0.020

0.005

0.008

-0.016

-0.001

(0.020)

(0.025)

(0.019)

(0.028)

(0.017)

Observations

527

445

579

289

552

Panel C: Countries where central bank does not have majority decision making power

Pre-election

-0.032

-0.024

-0.029

-0.046

-0.034

Pre-election Interaction

(0.024)

(0.023)

(0.022)

(0.028)

(0.024)

0.028

0.034

0.039

0.007

0.033

(0.028)

(0.033)

(0.036)

(0.029)

(0.020)

Observations

1,043

988

1,043

746

1,043

71

Table A15: Central Bank Independence and Election Cycles in Monetary Policy

Notes: This table shows coecients from estimating equation 1. The dependent variable is change in the central bank policy rate or the percentage change in central bank reserves. CBI is the measure of central bank independence from Dincer & Eichengreen (2014), extended using the data from Garriga (2016). All estimations include country fixed eects, year-quarter fixed eects, and the baseline control variables as described in the text except the growth in central bank reserves. For the policy rate I include four lags of the dependent variable, for reserves two lags. I treat the Eurozone as a single country in columns 1 and 2, and assign it the timing of German elections and the average of all control variables; the results are almost equivalent if I instead use country-specific elections and controls. Standard errors are clustered by country, with ***, **, and * denoting statistical significance at the 1%, 5%, and 10% level, respectively.

With Eurozone

Without Eurozone

Policy rate

CB reserves

Policy rate

CB reserves

(1)

(2)

(3)

(4)

Pre-election

-0.269*

0.077**

-0.307*

0.082***

Pre-election CBI

(0.152)

(0.031)

(0.160)

(0.032)

0.689*

-0.128**

0.773*

-0.140**

(0.397)

(0.057)

(0.417)

(0.059)

Observations

1,784

1,947

1,738

1,900

R2

0.342

0.517

0.339

0.521

Dep. variable mean

-0.115

0.090

-0.117

0.090

Country FE

Yes

Yes

Yes

Yes

Time FE

Yes

Yes

Yes

Yes

Controls

Yes

Yes

Yes

Yes

72

Figure A1: Changes in Macroprudential Policy Across Years and Countries

Panel A: Changes Across Years

40

20

0

−20

−40

2000

2001

2002

2003

2004

2005

2006

2007

2008

2009

2010

2011

2012

2013

2014

Tightening

Loosening

Panel B: Changes Across Countries

[0,1]

(1,6]

(6,11]

(11,16]

(16,21]

(21,26]

No data

Notes: These figures plots the total number of tightening and loosening episodes in the macroprudential regulation index of Cerutti et al. (2017) for all sample countries between 2000 and 2014.

73

Table A16: Comparing Datasets on Macroprudential Changes

Notes: This table plots the Pearson correlation coecients of changes to macroprudential regulation as iden- tified by Cerutti et al. (2017) ("IMF"), Budnik & Kleibl (2018) ("B&K"), and Kuttner & Shim (2016) ("K&S"). The number of overlapping observations is reported in square brackets. I always use the "applied" dates for the B&K dataset (which yields higher correlations). For Concentration/exposure limits, I use the IMF variable concrat, but results are similar for ibex (which refers to interbank exposures). For risk weights, I use the IMF variable sscb (also used for the sectoral capital buers). For reserve requirements, I use the IMF variable rr_local, but the results are similar for rr_foreign or combining both into one variable. For Liquidity requirements, I use the B&K category Liquidity requirements and limits on currency and maturity mismatch.

Corr(IMF,K&S)

Corr(IMF,B&K)

Corr(B&K,K&S)

(Sectoral) capital buers

0.0483

N

[1,560]

General capital requirements

0.2382

N

[1,560]

Concentration/exposure limits

-0.0731

0.1854

0.1416

N

[1,491]

[668]

[1,696]

Provisioning

0.2306

N

[1,696]

Risk weights

0.4264

0.3584

0.3311

N

[1,560]

[2,722]

[1,696]

Tax/Levy

0.0644

N

[1,696]

Reserve requirements

0.6872

0.4301

0.3519

N

[2,722]

[1,560]

[1,696]

LTV ratio

0.7953

0.4682

0.3328

N

[797]

[467]

[1,696]

D(S)TI ratio

0.6873

N

[1,696]

Credit growth

0.2235

N

[1,696]

Liquidity requirements

0.1251

N

[1,696]

74

Figure A2: Election Cycles in Other Datasets

Change in Regulation, K&S (2016)

Change in Regulation, B&K (2018)

.001

.1

0

08

.

−.001

.06

−.002

.04

−.003

.02

−.004

0

Pre−election quarter

All other quarters

Notes: This figure plots the arithmetic average net changes in macroprudential regulation in pre-election quarters and all other quarters based on the data from Kuttner & Shim (2016) and Budnik & Kleibl (2018). I calculate net changes as the sum of changes in all policy tools in a quarter. Positive values indicate a tightening, negative values a loosening of policy.

75

Figure A3: Placebo Test with Randomized Election Timing

4

3

Percent

2

1

0

Baseline estimate (t = −2.85)

−3

−2

−1

0

1

2

3

t−stat

ˆ

Notes: This figure plots the t-statistics of the estimated coe cients from regressing dummies for the tightening of sector-specific capital buers on 500 sets of placebo pre-election dummies. These placebo dummies are calculated by first choosing a random quarter between 2000q1 and the latest quarter one would expect the next election to take place (based on a country's typical practice or term limit), and then assuming that the following placebo elections through 2014q4 were "regular". All regressions include country year fixed eects, the baseline control variables, and one lag of the dependent variable. The red vertical lines indicate the coecients estimated with the same regression specification and the actual pre- election quarters in the data. Only 1% of the t-statistics of the placebo pre-election quarters yield smaller values than that in the data.

76

Imprint and acknowledgements

I would like to thank Anat Admati, David Aikman, Pat Akey (discussant), Jason Allen, David Archer, Thorsten Beck, Alan Blinder, Franziska Bremus, Jonathan Bridges, Matthieu Chavaz, Stijn Claessens, John Cochrane, Jihad Dagher, Mara Faccio, David Finer, Julia Fonseca (discussant), Stuart Fraser, Thomas Fujiwara, Andreas Fuster, Rainer Haselmann, Boris Hofmann, Adam Honig, Anil Kashyap, Paymon Khorrami, Adrien Matray, Atif Mian, James Mitchell, Andrea Presbitero, David Samuel, Moritz Schularick, Rhiannon Sowerbutts, Till Stowasser (discussant), Emil Verner, and Luigi Zingales for helpful discussions as well as conference and seminar participants at the Political Economy of Finance Conference, Princeton University, IMF, BIS, SNB, the Bundesbank Conference on Financial Cycles and Regulation, Bank of England, CFIC 2019, and the University of Bonn for their comments. Part of the work on this paper was conducted while I was visiting the University of Chicago's Booth School of Business and the Bank of England, whose hospitality is gratefully acknowledged. Christian Kontz provided excellent research assistance. I was supported by a Doctoral Training Centre scholarship granted by the Economic and Social Research Council [grant number 1500313]. All remaining errors are mine.

Karsten Müller

Princeton University, Princeton, United States; email: karstenm@princeton.edu

© European Systemic Risk Board, 2019

Postal address

60640 Frankfurt am Main, Germany

Telephone

+49 69 1344 0

Website

www.esrb.europa.eu

All rights reserved. Reproduction for educational and non-commercial purposes is permitted provided that the source is acknowledged.

Note:

The views expressed in ESRB Working Papers are those of the authors and do not necessarily reflect the official stance of the ESRB, its member institutions, or the institutions to which the authors are affiliated.

ISSN

2467-0677 (pdf)

ISBN

978-92-9472-120-4 (pdf)

DOI

10.2849/88680 (pdf)

EU catalogue No

DT-AD-19-020-EN-N (pdf)

Attachments

  • Original document
  • Permalink

Disclaimer

ESRB - European Systemic Risk Board published this content on 16 December 2019 and is solely responsible for the information contained therein. Distributed by Public, unedited and unaltered, on 16 December 2019 11:10:04 UTC