Working Paper Series

Mirco Balatti, Carolina López-QuilesLimited liability, strategic default

and bargaining power

No 2519 / January 2021

Disclaimer: This paper should not be reported as representing the views of the European Central Bank (ECB). The views expressed are those of the authors and do not necessarily reflect those of the ECB.

Abstract

In this paper we examine the eects of limited liability on mortgage dynamics. While the literature has focused on default rates, renegotiation, or loan rates individually, we study them together as equilibrium outcomes of the strategic interaction between lenders and borrowers. We present a simple model of default and renegotiation where the degree of limited liability plays a key role in agents' strategies. We then use Fannie Mae loan performance data to test the predictions of the model. We focus on Metropolitan Statistical Areas that are crossed by a State border in order to exploit the discontinuity in regulation around the borders of States. As predicted by the model, we nd that limited liability results in higher default rates and renegotiation rates. Regarding loan pricing, while the model predicts higher interest rates for limited liability loans, we nd no such evidence in the Fannie Mae data. We further investigate this by using loan application data, which contains the interest rates on loans sold to private vs public investors. We nd that private investors do price in the dierence in ex-ante predictable default risk for limited liability loans.

JEL codes: D10, E40, G21, R20, R30

Keywords: lender recourse, mortgage contracts, debt repudiation, renegotiation, discon-

tinuity.

ECB Working Paper Series No 2519 / January 2021

1

Non-technical summary

The rise of household debt before the nancial crisis combined with high default rates was a root cause of the Great Recession and highlighted the role of consumer nance for the macroeconomy. Mortgage debt, in particular, constitutes two-thirds of US household total debt. Outstanding mortgage amounts declined substantially during the Great Recession, but have since reached new historical highs.

While there are several factors that determine the rate of mortgage default, such as adverse economic shocks that leave households unable to honour their debt, default may also be a voluntary choice, commonly referred to as strategic default. One particular aspect the household may consider before choosing to default is whether there is limited or full liability in place. Under limited liability, the lender is not allowed to seize the household's assets after default.

Limited liability constitutes the legal protection of a stakeholder's liabilities beyond a xed sum. In the context of loans, and in particular of mortgage contracts, limited liability implies a xed limit on the borrower's obligations, which amounts to the handover of the mortgaged property. In the absence of limited liability, the borrower is liable for the repayment of the full loan amount, and the lender is entitled to seize the borrower's personal assets.

In contrast to the literature, which has studied several eects of limited liability indi- vidually, we analyse default decisions, renegotiation and loan pricing together. These are, in fact, equilibrium outcomes of the strategic interaction between lenders and borrowers. To this end, we rst develop a simple model of default and renegotiation where the degree of limited liability plays a key role in agents' strategies. Borrowers who can aord to pay the loan may choose to default if their mortgage is underwater. Limited liability encour-

ECB Working Paper Series No 2519 / January 2021

2

ages this behaviour since borrowers can walk away from their debt more easily. In turn, lenders may be inclined to oer renegotiated loan prices to these borrowers, as they know under limited liability they would not be able to recover more than the foreclosure value of the home. Borrowers thus have greater bargaining power over lenders under limited liability. These interactions also have an eect on loan prices, as the expected value of each loan will depend on the equilibrium of this game. Thus, the model provides three main predictions. First, limited liability leads to higher default rates. Second, lenders renegotiate more under limited liability. Lastly, loan prices are higher for limited liability loans.

We then use Fannie Mae loan performance data to test the predictions of the model. We exploit the dierence in regulation in dierent States. In particular, we limit our analysis to Metropolitan Statistical Areas (MSAs) that are crossed by a State border, where one side has limited liability laws in place and the other does not. This allows us to isolate the eect of limited liability on loan outcomes, as other factors such as economic shocks are expected to be the same within each MSA. As predicted by the model, we nd that limited liability results in higher default and renegotiation rates. Regarding loan pricing, while the model predicts higher interest rates for limited liability loans, we nd no such evidence in the Fannie Mae data. We further investigate this by using loan application data from the Home Mortgage Disclosure Act (HMDA) database, which contains the interest rates on loans sold to private and public purchasers. We nd that private investors do price in the dierence in ex-ante predictable default risk for limited liability loans, while their public counterparts, such as Fannie Mae, do not. This has important policy implications, as it imposes price distortions in a multi-trillion dollar market.

ECB Working Paper Series No 2519 / January 2021

3

  • Introduction

The rise of household indebtedness before the nancial crisis combined with high default rates was a root cause of the Great Recession and underlined the importance of consumer nance for the macroeconomy. Mortgage debt, in particular, constitutes two-thirds of US household total debt, as shown in Figure 1. Outstanding mortgage amounts declined substantially during the Great Recession, but have since reached new historical highs.

Figure 1: US households debt

Notes: Share of mortgage and other debt types as a percentage of total household debt. Total US outstanding mortgage amount in trillion US dollars. Source: New York Fed Consumer Credit Panel/Equifax and authors own calculations, 2003-2019.

While there are several factors that determine the rate of mortgage default, such as adverse economic shocks that leave households unable to honour their debt, default may also be a voluntary choice, commonly referred to as strategic default. One particular aspect the household may consider before choosing to default is whether there is limited in place. Under limited liability, the lender is not allowed to seize the household's assets

ECB Working Paper Series No 2519 / January 2021

4

after default.

Precisely because of the widespread presence of mortgage debt, and in order to prevent strategic default, some jurisdictions allow for lender recourse. Under recourse, lenders are allowed to seize borrowers' assets after default. This aspect of mortgage contracts is predominant in Europe, as noted by Campbell (2012). In the case of the United States, the existence of mortgage recourse is heterogeneous across States, a feature which we will exploit in our analysis.

Strategic default has been widely studied for sovereign debt (e.g. Grossman and Van Huyck (1988); Atkeson (1991)), and other types of unsecured debt (e.g. Jeske (2006)). Mortgage debt is a particular case, and it is interesting to evaluate it in isolation. First, agents making decisions are not sovereign States or investors, but households. Second, debt contracts are highly structured and backed by a real estate property. Third, this type of collateral, in addition to providing an investment opportunity, grants housing services to the borrower. This non-monetary function allows households to derive additional utility from the asset and can thus heavily inuence their choices. Fourth, mortgage contracts typically allow borrowers to reach levels of leverage uncommon in other types of debt. Lastly, mortgage contracts are typically longer, the most common contract length being around 30 years. It is worth noting that the decisions made by agents may di er substantially as the loan is amortised.

In order to understand the mechanisms at hand, it is important to review the chain of events after default, and the payo s from which agents will derive their decisions. When a household defaults on a mortgage, the lender recovers the collateral through foreclosure, short sale, or a deed in lieu. Under limited liability, the borrower is freed from their debt and the lender only recovers the proceedings from the sale of the property. In contrast, under recourse or full liability, the lender can pursue a de ciency judgement.

ECB Working Paper Series No 2519 / January 2021

5

A deciency judgement is a ruling through which the lender calculates the dierence between the mortgage balance outstanding and the amount recovered through the sale of the collateral. Should the sale of the collateral not be enough to cover the mortgage balance, the lender is entitled to claim the dierence from the borrower.

This paper relates to two bodies of literature. The rst one exploits dierent legislative discontinuities around State borders to study several aspects of limited liability and its eect on dierent market outcomes. Some papers have focused on the eect of limited liability on loan origination. Pence (2006) studies loan origination volumes through the dierence in the size of loans on recourse and non-recourse States and nds that non- recourse loans are smaller on average. Curtis (2014) nds that lender-friendly foreclosure is associated with an increase in subprime originations, but has less eect on the prime market. Li and Oswald (2017) leverage on the abolition of deciency judgements in the State of Nevada in 2009 and nd that it led to a decline in equilibrium loan sizes and approval rates. Some other papers have studied the eect of limited liability on loan rates and housing prices. Meador (1982) nds that States with judicial foreclosure exhibit lower interest rates on loans. Pennington-Cross and Ho (2008) inquire whether laws intending to reduce predatory lending behaviour have an eect on loan rates. Their results suggest that these laws have only a modest eect on loan prices. Mian et al. (2015) use judicial requirements for foreclosures across States as an instrument for foreclosures and nd that higher foreclosure rates lead to a decline in house prices, residential investments and consumer demand. Another set of papers is concerned with forbearance and loan modications. Gerardi et al. (2013) nd that laws designed to protect borrowers delay but do not prevent foreclosure. Conditional on a loan being underwater, these laws do not increase the probability of cure. Collins et al. (2011) test the extent to which distressed mortgage borrowers benet from dierent types of State foreclosure polices. They nd that judicial foreclosure proceedings and foreclosure prevention initiatives are associated

ECB Working Paper Series No 2519 / January 2021

6

with modest increases in loan modication rates. Finally, another group of papers focus on the eect of dierent legislation on default rates. Ghent and Kudlyak (2011) compare recourse and non-recourse States and nd higher mortgage default rates in the latter. Chan et al. (2016) examine how factors aecting mortgage default spill over to other credit markets. They nd that, while non-recourse mortgage laws increase mortgage default, they are associated with lower credit card default. Gianinazzi et al. (2019) investigate default behaviour in Europe, where all mortgages have lender recourse and conclude that many households default when the value of the house is greater than the outstanding mortgage balance. They nd this result puzzling because it is suboptimal. The authors rationalise it by arguing that, under recourse, the fear of a decline in house prices pushes these households to anticipate their default decision, thereby 'leaving money on the table'. While these papers focus on individual aspects on limited liability, one contribution of this paper is to encompass default, renegotiation and loan pricing in an integrated setting. We consider this an important aspect, as these elements are all equilibrium outcomes of the strategic interaction between borrowers and lenders, which we show in our model.

The second strand of the literature this paper relates to deals with discrepancies between Government-Sponsored Enterprises (GSEs) and the private market. Most notably, Hurst et al. (2016) nd that despite large regional variation in predictable default risk, GSE mortgage rates for otherwise identical loans do not vary spatially. In contrast, they nd that the private market does set interest rates which vary with local risk. In this regard, Dagher and Sun (2016) nd similar results for credit supply by exploiting an exogenous cuto in loan eligibility to GSE guarantees. They nd that judicial requirements reduce the supply of credit only for jumbo loans, which are ineligible for GSE guarantees.

In this paper we connect these two strands of the literature by analysing default and renegotiation choices by borrowers and lenders, as well as loan pricing, and to highlight the dierence in pricing between private and public investors.

ECB Working Paper Series No 2519 / January 2021

7

In addition, this paper is related to the theoretical literature that studies debt and renegotiation, of which the closest papers are Hart and Moore (1998) and Bester (1994). Some other papers have studied mortgage contracts and default decisions through the lens of a dynamic heterogeneous agents model in general equilibrium. Some examples of such models are Kaplan et al. (2017) and Guren et al. (2018). Guren et al. (2018) investigate the interaction of adjustable and xed-rate mortgage contracts with monetary policy. Kaplan et al. (2017) propose a life-cycle model of housing decisions with both idiosyncratic and aggregate shocks. Their goal is to replicate the macroeconomic dynamics observed in the data during the Great Recession. These papers focus exclusively on non-recourse mortgages.

In what follows, we present a model of debt renegotiation where the strategic choices of lenders and borrowers depend on the extent to which recourse is enforced. In the model, both house prices and the income of the borrower are stochastic. In some states of the world, the household has enough income to pay their mortgage, whereas in other states of the world it does not. Likewise, in some states of the world, the house value is higher than the mortgage amount, i.e. the household has positive equity, whereas in other states of the world the house value is lower, i.e. the mortgage is underwater. Households who can a ord to meet their payments, but whose mortgage is underwater, may nd it optimal to default, in particular on instances where it is unlikely that they will be liable with their personal assets after default. Lenders who know this may nd it optimal to o er these households a renegotiated mortgage price in order to prevent them from walking away from their obligations. At the same time, the price of these loans will reect these mechanisms.

We test the predictions of this model exploiting the di erence in mortgage laws in di erent US States. We focus on Metropolitan Statistical Areas that are crossed by a State border, where one State has limited liability laws in place while the other does

ECB Working Paper Series No 2519 / January 2021

8

not. Using Fannie Mae loan performance data we nd, as predicted by the model, that default rates are higher for lower levels of lender recourse, and so are renegotiation rates. However, one result is at odds with our model: there appears to be no signicant dierence in the interest rate charged on loans across State borders. Importantly, this nding adds to the notion that GSEs do not appropriately price regional dierences in the likelihood of default, as pointed out by Hurst et al. (2016). We further investigate this by using loan application data from loans that were sold to private and public buyers. We nd a statistically and economically signicant dierence in loan rates in the private market, as opposed to the ndings on GSE pricing. We hence advance to the debate on the dierences in pricing between private and public entities by including its interaction with limited liability.

These results have non-negligible economic and policy implications. Since observable dierences in local mortgage regulation yield dierent ex-ante predictable default risk, the lack of price discrimination implies mispricing by GSEs. This is an important distortion in a multi-trillion dollar market. The GSE's single rate policy across jurisdictions generates ineciencies, which is a cost to taxpayers. On the contrary, private investors of securitised loans are less subject to such costs. In addition, friendly borrowing conditions can increase demand for homes in limited liability jurisdictions, which could generate divergence in house prices across States.

In sum, this paper contributes to the literature along several dimensions. First, we add to the theoretical literature by modelling limited liability explicitly. Furthermore, we incorporate it as a key parameter dened on a continuum, which allows us to identify the dierent equilibria of the game for dierent degrees of enforcement of limited liability law. Other features of the model, such as stochastic income and house prices enhance its richness and permit a better characterisation of the equilibria in dierent states of the world. This is needed to formalise pricing of mortgages theoretically, taking into

ECB Working Paper Series No 2519 / January 2021

9

account the propensity of default and renegotiation observed in equilibrium, as well as the expected values of household income and house prices. We thus also contribute to the empirical literature, which has studied default and renegotiation individually in partial equilibrium by using this model as a guide for the empirical testing of its implications.

The conclusions of the model are non-trivial.Ex-post, i.e. once a mortgage contract is sealed, the bargaining power given to borrowers by limited liability intuitively points to higher default and renegotiation. Yet, ex-ante lenders know the limited liability law and could be expected to adjust their strategies accordingly, via higher prices or ex- ante commitment to a lower renegotiation propensity in order to disincentivise strategic default. The model suggests that equilibrium pricing should be dierent but does not point to less renegotiation oering, as in this setting it would represent a non-credible threat.

While the data conrms model predictions regarding default and renegotiation, we nd mispricing of ex-ante known strategic default risk in GSEs. This represents an additional dimension of ineciencies in GSEs, previously unknown in the literature. We therefore also contribute to the literature that has studied loan pricing by GSEs by highlighting the lack of dierential pricing along a regulatory dimension.

The rest of the paper is organised as follows. Section 2 proposes a simple model of the strategic interactions between lenders and borrowers and outlines the optimal rates of default, renegotiation, and loan prices. Section 3 describes the data and explains the identication strategy. Section 4 lays out the results for the empirical tests of the model predictions and elaborates on the loan pricing dierence between private and public investors. Finally, Section 5 concludes.

ECB Working Paper Series No 2519 / January 2021

10

  • The Model

This model draws from Bester (1994) model of debt renegotiation with collateral, where we incorporate lender recourse. There are two time periods t = f0; 1g. Consider a household who wants to buy a house. The house has a purchase price R in period 0. In period 1, the house changes value stochastically to R(s), where s 2 fsH ; sLg denotes the state of the world. We assume sH realises with probability n, and sL with probability 1 n. The household has no initial wealth so it borrows an amount M = R to purchase the property. In t = 1, the household will have to pay an amount P equal to the principal plus some non-negative interest, so P M. In period t = 1 the household receives an exogenous income, which can be either high, YH , with probability p, or low, YL with probability 1 p.

There is asymmetric information about the realisation of income, but the market value of the house in t = 1 is public information. All distributions are public information, so the bank knows the probability that YH or YL realise, that is, it knows p. Asymmetric information implies that the lender cannot write a contract contingent on income.

In the event of default, the bank can choose to foreclose the property, which yields a return of R(s) (where < 1 represents the recovery rate considering foreclosure costs), or to renegotiate the payment price, oering an alternative payment P 0 .

If the bank chooses to foreclose the property, and in order to model the mortgage recourse laws outlined in the previous section, we assume that after foreclosure, there is a judge ruling about the deciency judgement, which can entitle the bank to seize the household's income for the dierence between the amount owed, P , and the amount recovered in foreclosure, R(s). We assume the judge rules for a deciency judgement with probability . The limited liability case, or non-recourse, is the nested case where the

ECB Working Paper Series No 2519 / January 2021

11

parameter = 0, i.e. the law rules out deciency judgements.

It is clear that in the event of a low income realisation, the household is forced to de- fault. With a high income realisation, however, the household may default strategically. Then, the right to foreclose, together with the extent of lender recourse play an important role in incentivising payment by the high income household.

To sum up, a debt contract species a payment amount P , and entitles the lender to seize the borrower's personal assets (income) with exogenous probability . Lender recourse is a threat that may induce the high income household to pay. At the same time, the extent of lender recourse will aect the incentives for the lender to renegotiate and oer a lower payment price. This is because, under limited liability, i.e. non-recourse, by not renegotiating the bank may be committing to an ex post inecient outcome. This happens when the foreclosure value of the property is lower than the potential renegotiated payment P 0 . It is therefore interesting to consider the following game in t = 1:

ECB Working Paper Series No 2519 / January 2021

12

Figure 2: Game in t = 1

Nature

1

p

p

Household

Household

d

1

d

default

Bank

(YH

P + R(s);

r

1

r

r

1

P

M)

r

Nature

Nature

(YL

P 0 + R(s),

(YH

P 0 + R(s);

P 0

M)

P 0

M)

1

1

(YL;

(YH ;

R(s) M)

R(s) M)

(maxfYL

(P

R(s)); 0g;

R(s) + minf(P

R(s)); YLg M)

(maxfYH (P

R(s)); 0g;

R(s) + minf(P

R); YH g M)

where p denotes the probability of high income, d denotes the probability with which the household chooses to default, r denotes the probability with which the bank chooses to renegotiate the payment amount, and indicates the probability of a deciency judgement. The dotted area indicates the information set of the bank in the second stage. It observes that the household has defaulted, but it doesn't know whether this default was strategic, i.e. whether the household has high income. The payos of the household and the bank are reported below the ending nodes, respectively.

In order to simplify the game and to focus on the most interesting parts of the mech- anism, we make the following assumptions about the relative values of the parameters:

Assumption 1. YH > P > YL. The household can only aord the mortgage payment amount if it receives a high realisation of income.

ECB Working Paper Series No 2519 / January 2021

13

This assumption places the model in the interesting case where some households are nancially unable to meet their obligations.

Assumption 2. R(s) < YL. The foreclosure value of the house is lower than the low realisation of income in all states of the world s.

This assumption yields the interesting case where the bank would be able to recover more by renegotiating than by foreclosing the property.

Assumption 3. P R(s) > YL. The low income household cannot aord the deciency judgement for all s.

From the assumption that YH > P it is clear that YH > P R(s), i.e. the high income household can always aord the deciency judgement. If the low income household could also pay the deciency judgement, i.e. if YL > P R(s), then the asymmetry of information around the realisation of income would be irrelevant to the bank's decision to renegotiate because it would get the same expected return whether the household has high or low income. We impose P R(s) > YL in order to focus on the more interesting case where asymmetric information about the borrower's realisation of income, together with the fact that the low income household cannot pay the deciency judgement, introduces an interesting mechanism for the renegotiation of the price.

Corollary 1. P 0 = YL. The renegotiated price is equal to the low realisation of income.

It is clear that if P 0 > YL, the low income household cannot aord the renegotiated price, and will pay at most YL, so the renegotiation price must be equal to the low realization of income.

In order to characterise the equilibria of the game, it is important to note two cases:

ECB Working Paper Series No 2519 / January 2021

14

whether P < R(s), i.e. the household has positive equity on the mortgage, or P > R(s), i.e. the mortgage is underwater.

Assumption 4. R(sL) < P < R(sH ). The values of the house in dierent states of the world are such that the repayment price of the mortgage falls between them. That is, the low value of the house is lower than the price of the mortgage, while the high value of the house is higher, i.e. the mortgage is underwater when sL realises.

In the case of positive equity, i.e. state sH , the equilibria of this game imply no default and no renegotiation. The borrower would not nd it optimal to give up the house when they can aord the mortgage, given that the house value is higher than the payment amount unless it gets a renegotiation oer. In turn, the lender would not nd it optimal to renegotiate if they know this is the case. In fact, by choosing r = 0 the lender can guarantee that the borrower will choose d = 0 since for the high income household

YH P + R(sH ) > YH (P R(sH ))

where the inequality comes from the fact that 2 [0; 1] and P < R(sH ).

In sum, r = 0 is a dominant strategy for the lender, independently of , in which case only the low income household defaults.

In state sL, when the mortgage is underwater, one can show that the dominant strategy is not to default if YH realises, i.e. d = 0 unless

P R(sL)

(1)

P

R(sL)

In this case, the lender will choose r = 1 if

YL R(sL) + [(1

p)YL + p(P

R(sL))]; i:e:

YL R(sL)

(2)

p(P R(sL)) + (1 p)YL

ECB Working Paper Series No 2519 / January 2021

15

Alternatively, the lender will choose r = 0 if

YL R(sL) + [(1 p)YL + p(P

R(sL))]; i:e:

YL R(sL)

(3)

p(P R(sL)) + (1 p)YL

In the case where (2) holds with equality (and therefore (3) as well), the lender will rst observe the borrower's strategy, and choose r = 0 if d = 0, or mix r 2 (0; 1) if d = 1.

Proposition 1. If P < R(s) there is a unique pure strategy equilibrium with d = 0 and r=0 independently of . If P > R(s) the is a pure strategy equilibrium when condition

  1. and (2) are satised with strict inequality with d = 1 and r = 0, while if (1) and (3) are satised with strict inequality, the equilibrium is given by d = 1 and r = 1; therefore, when (1) is satised with strict inequality and (3) is satised with equality, any r 2 (0; 1)

and d = 1 is an equilibrium, and when (1) is satised with equality and (3) is satised with strict inequality, any d 2 (0; 1) and r = 1 is an equilibrium.

The equilibria of this game will therefore depend on the value of and the relative position of thresholds (1) and (2) when they hold with equality. Figure 3 provides a graphical representation of the equilibria as a function of when when (1) > (2). As can be seen, for high values of , there is no default or renegotiation in equilibrium. This is because high lender recourse imposes too high a cost for the high income household to default, as it may risk a deciency judgement. Knowing this, the lender chooses to not renegotiate. As lender recourse decreases, the borrower starts facing higher incentives to default, as the risk of a deciency judgement is lower. When (1) holds with equality, there is no renegotiation and the borrower mixes between default and repayment. For values of lambda between (1) and (2), it is optimal for the household to default, as the risk of a deciency judgement is below the threshold, but it is still not optimal for the lender

ECB Working Paper Series No 2519 / January 2021

16

to renegotiate, as the expected payo from doing so continues to be lower than that of renegotiating. This is because, for the lender, the probability of a deciency judgement is still high enough such that in expectation they would recover more from the judgement than from the low renegotiated price YL. For below (2), the incentive for renegotiation kicks in for the lender, as the probability of a deciency judgement is too low and hence the renegotiated price is higher than the expected recovery value from a foreclosed property. Equilibria for the cases where (1) < (2) and (1) = (2) can be found in Appendix A. In all cases, the equilibria with default and renegotiation appear as decreases. Hence, the testable implication is that default and renegotiation are higher in non-recourse States. We will test this in the next Section.

Figure 3: Equilibria when (1) > (2) as a function of

We now turn to the pricing decision by the bank. With bank competition, a risk- neutral bank will set a repayment price P in t = 0 so as to set the expected value of the game in t = 1 equal to zero. The bank knows the value of , and it anticipates the equilibrium of the game for each state of the world. Hence, there are three cases:

ECB Working Paper Series No 2519 / January 2021

17

First, when > (1), the bank knows that under any realisation of the house value, it is always optimal for the high income household not to default. It therefore anticipates the equilibrium where d = 0 and r = 0. The expected value of the game is then

(1 p)h(nRH + (1 n)RL) + YL Mi + p(P M) = 0

(4)

so

P>(1) = (1 p)hM (nRH + (1 n)RL) YLi + M (5) p

Second, when (1) > > (2), the bank anticipates that the household will default if

the low house value realises. Therefore the expected value of the game is

+(1 n)h(1

nh(1

p)[RH + YL

M] + p(P

M)i

(6)

p)[RL + YL M] + p[RL + P

M]i = 0

so

P(1)>>(2)

=

(1 p)

[M

YL nRH

(1

n)RL]

p

n + (1

n)

(7)

M

RL

+

n)

n + (1

Third, when < (2), the bank anticipates that under the low realisation of the house value the household will default, and it also nds it optimal to renegotiate, that is, d = 1

and r = 1. The expected value of the game is then

nh(1

p)[RH + YL

M] + p(P

M)i

(8)

+(1

n)[YL

M] = 0

so

(1

p)

M

(1

n)

P<(2) =

[M RH YL] +

+

[M YL]

(9)

p

n

np

ECB Working Paper Series No 2519 / January 2021

18

It can be shown that P is decreasing in in all cases, that is, that for higher lender recourse, mortgage rates are lower.

This model outlines the mechanism we want to highlight and provides testable impli- cations. Namely, that for higher levels of lender recourse, underwater borrowers default at a higher rate even when they have the means to pay for their mortgage. Lenders are incentivised to renegotiate the price of the mortgage in cases where lender recourse is low, as is the case in limited liability States. Loan prices therefore should reect this. However, as we will see in the next Section, Government Sponsored Enterprises such as Fannie Mae, do not set loan prices di erently across jurisdictions with di erent levels of lender recourse. The fact that in the US most mortgages are bought by GSEs, which are government-guaranteed, implies that in the end this deadweight loss is borne by the taxpayer. We now turn to empirically verify the relationship between recourse laws and mortgage prices, default probabilities, and renegotiation.

  • Data and Methodology

3.1 Fannie Mae Single Family Loan Database

This database contains acquisition data from all the mortgage loans acquired by Fannie Mae, together with monthly performance data of said loans. Acquisition data includes variables such as the seller name, original unpaid balance, original loan term, origination date, original loan-to-value (LTV) ratio, original debt-to-income (DTI) ratio, borrower credit score (FICO score), loan purpose, property type and mortgage insurance percent and type. Performance data includes variables such as current interest rate, current unpaid balance, loan age, remaining months to maturity, delinquency status, last paid instalment date, foreclosure date, foreclosure costs, asset recovery costs and other costs, taxes, net sale proceeds and other proceeds and principal forgiveness amount. Location data of the property is also available. In particular, the State, the Metropolitan Statistical Area (MSA) and the 3-digit Zip code are reported. Data is available on a monthly basis

ECB Working Paper Series No 2519 / January 2021

19

from 2004 to 2016.

We focus exclusively on purchase loans for principal home, to abstract from the difference in default incentives that may be present for mortgage loans used for investment purposes. We consider a loan to have defaulted once it is over 90 days delinquent, as is standard in the literature. However, we note that our results are robust to other denitions of default.1

3.2 Home Mortgage Disclosure Act Database

The Home Mortgage Disclosure Act (HMDA) Database contains the universe of all mortgage loan applications led by reporting banks in the United States. Banks are obliged to report if their balance sheet size is above a certain threshold. The information on each application includes loan characteristics such as the loan amount and the purpose of the loan (purchase, renance or home improvement); borrower and co-borrower characteristics such as income, race and gender; and characteristics of the property such as its geographical location (Metropolitan Statistical Area, census tract, State, ...), occupancy and type of dwelling (single-family, multifamily, ...).

In addition, the database includes information about whether the loan was granted or not, and the reasons for denial where applicable.

We use this database to explore the dierences in the characteristics of the demand for loans, as well as lenders' willingness to lend conditional on loan characteristics between recourse and non-recourse States.

  • For instance, we consider a loan to have defaulted if it has been delinquent for over 90 days at any point in time and has not gone back to current status in the 12 months prior to the end of its reporting life, i.e. no recovery in the 12 months prior to it being sold to a third party, foreclosed or otherwise nalised. Another denition, used by Ghent and Kudlyak (2011), considers a loan to have defaulted when it is terminated by short sale, deed in lieu or REO sale.

ECB Working Paper Series No 2519 / January 2021

20

HP ItHP I0

This data is available on a yearly basis from 2004 to 2016.

3.3 Federal Housing Finance Agency database

In order to assert the value of the collateral of each mortgage at each point in time, we use House Price Indices from the Federal Housing Finance Agency. They are estimates using all transactions of sold houses in a given period and 3-digit ZIP code. These data are used to estimate the current value of the property and the current equity value of the mortgage owner.

Following the literature, we compute the market price of a house at time t as follows:

Pt = P0

HP It

(10)

HP I0

where P0 is the purchase price of the house at the time it was acquired by the borrower,

and is the growth of the Housing Price Index in the period between the home

purchase (time 0) and the present time.

3.4 Identication

Our identication strategy consists of comparing mortgage loans of homes located in recourse and non-recourse States over their life cycle in order to understand the eect of dierent regulations on dierent outcomes.

In order to exploit the discontinuity around the border of recourse and non-recourse States, we focus on Metropolitan Statistical Areas that are crossed by a State border. First, let us dene what an MSA is:

The United States Oce of Management and Budget (OMB) delineates metropolitan and micropolitan statistical areas according to published standards that are applied to Census Bureau data. The general concept of a metropolitan or mi- cropolitan statistical area is that of a core area containing a substantial population nucleus, together with adjacent communities having a high degree of

ECB Working Paper Series No 2519 / January 2021

21

economic and social integration with that core. United States Census Bureau.

Mortgages in the same MSA are arguably exposed to the same economic shocks since MSAs are delineated by denition to encompass geographical areas that are 'economi- cally and socially integrated'. Households on either side of such borders are expected to be exposed to the same economic shocks, so a dierence in our variables of interest can be interpreted as stemming from the dierence in borrower liability.

We dene recourse and non-recourse States following Ghent and Kudlyak (2011). The resulting dataset, in which we select MSAs that are crossed by a State border where one side of the border enforces recourse and the other does not, spans 6 Metropolitan Statistical Areas and 9 States, as shown in Table 1. For the Fannie Mae monthly loan performance data, this implies over 100,000 individual loans over and 4 million observa- tions, while for the Home Mortgage Disclosure Act loan application data we have almost

3.5 million individual loan applications.

Table 1: Metropolitan Statistical Areas

MSA Name

Recourse side

Non-recourse side

Charlotte-Concord-Gastonia

SC

NC

Davenport-Moline-Rock Island

IL

IA

Lewiston

ID

WA

Omaha-Council Blus

NE

IA

Sioux City

SD, NE

IA

Virginia Beach-Norfolk-Newport

VA

NC

Notes: Names of the Metropolitan Statistical Areas that are crossed by a State border where one State enforces lender recourse and the other does not. The second and third columns present the abbreviations of the States on either side. Recourse and non-recourse are dened following Ghent and Kudlyak (2011).

ECB Working Paper Series No 2519 / January 2021

22

  • Empirical Analysis

4.1 Testing the Model predictions: the pricing puzzle

In this section we use the Fannie Mae Single Family Loan Performance database to test

the predictions from the model. Table 2 shows the mean values for some key variables,

separated by recourse and non-recourse, together with the p-values for the two-sidedt-test

of whether they are statistically di erent from each other.

Table 2: Descriptive Statistics

Non-recourse Recourse p-value

Variables at origination

Rate of default (%)

3.24

2.15

<.001

Loan Amount ($)

196,477

181,003

<.001

Credit Score

750.9

755.6

<.001

Interest Rate (%)

4.85

4.84

.06

Debt-to-income (%)

33.46

33.83

<.001

Loan-to-value (%)

80.32

80.01

<.001

Current variables

Current Balance ($)

170,202

157,804

<.001

Current Interest Rate (%)

4.98

4.97

<.001

Market Price ($)

250,118

227,611

<.001

Months to Maturity

311

310

<.001

N. of loans

48,406

51,892

.

N. of observations

2,044,322

2,174,763

.

Notes: Loan amount, current balance and market price are in US dollar amounts, interest rate, current interest rate, debt-to-income (DTI) and loan- to-value (LTV) are reported as percentages. DTI is calculated as the ratio between the borrower's total monthly obligations and their stable monthly income. Credit score is the FICO score. Source: Fannie Mae Single Family Loan Database, Federal Housing Finance Agency and authors own calcula- tions, 2004-2016.

We consider a loan to have defaulted, as is standard in the literature, when it has

delinquency status for longer than 3 months. Default rates are higher in non-recourse

States, as predicted by the model, while interest rates at origination are not statistically

di erent across jurisdictions. This is puzzling, as one would expect the higher risk of

default to be reected on prices. We will explore this more formally in the course of

ECB Working Paper Series No 2519 / January 2021

23

this section. Credit scores are lower on average on the non-recourse side of the border. While this dierence is statistically signicant, it is not economically signicant as the magnitude of the dierence is only 5 points in the FICO score. One may worry that there is self-selection into purchasing a house on either side of the border. Lower quality borrowers may choose to live on the non-recourse side of the border since they expect they may need to default with higher probability. This would bias our results. However, this small dierence in the credit score is reassuring that borrower quality is similar on either side of the border.

In addition, Debt-to-income ratios are also very similar. Debt-to-income ratios are a good way to measure the likelihood of default of a household, as it measures the strain that their debt places on their nances. The fact that these ratios are similar across jurisdictions, together with our use of the discontinuity around the border which ensures similar exposure to economic shocks, indicates that households can be expected to be able to meet their nancial obligations with similar probability. This relates to the model along parameter p, that is, the probability that the household will receive a low income realisation and not be able to meet their payments. Furthermore, Loan-to-value ratios seem to also be similar across jurisdictions, and very close to the regulatory soft limit of 80%. We call this a soft limit because banks are allowed to issue loans for more than 80% of the value of the property, but in order to do so, they must meet additional requirements, which makes 80% the eective limit for a wide majority of loans. Overall, it appears that most variables are similar in recourse and non-recourse States, which allows us to compare these loans and draw conclusions on the relevant variables of interest.

Next, we formally test the model predictions using dierent regressions. First, the model predicts that default rates should be higher in non-recourse States. We test this using the following Logit regression:

ECB Working Paper Series No 2519 / January 2021

24

LD = 0 + 1DNR + 3Xi;t + i;t

(11)

where LD denotes the log odds of default, DNR is a dummy variable that takes value 1 if the house is located in a non-recourse State and 0 otherwise, and Xi;t is the set of control variables. Control variables include the credit score of the borrower, the remaining loan term, the debt-to-income ratio of the borrower, the loan's current outstanding balance and the market price of the property.

Second, the model shows that, when faced with a delinquent borrower, the bank must choose whether to renegotiate the loan payment or let the household default. The model predicts that the bank chooses to renegotiate with lower probability as decreases. That implies that we should expect lower levels of renegotiation, conditional on the borrower being delinquent, in non-recourse States. We test the dierence in renegotiation rates between recourse and non-recourse States, conditional on the loan being more than 3 months delinquent, which is consistent with the standard denition of default used in the literature. The Logit regression in this case reads:

LM = 0 + 1DNR + 3Xi;t + i;t

(12)

where LM denotes the log odds of loan modication and the rest of the variables are dened as in the previous regression.

Finally, the model prediction is that prices should be higher on non-recourse States, owing to the higher level of ex-ante predictable risk. We run an OLS regression to test for the dierence in loan prices at origination:

ratei;t = 0 + 1DNR + 3Xi;t + i;t

(13)

where ratei;t is the interest rate agreed in the initial terms, and Xi;t are a set of con-

ECB Working Paper Series No 2519 / January 2021

25

trol variables. The control variables, in this case, are the credit score of the borrower, the initial loan term and the debt to income ratio of the borrower at origination.

Table 3 shows the results from these regressions. Columns 1-4 report Logit coecient estimates in odds ratios to facilitate the comparison and interpretation of the relative probability of default and renegotiation between recourse and non-recourse States. Values above (below) unity indicate a positive (negative) relation between the independent variable and the likelihood of default or renegotiation. As shown in Column 2, default rates are higher in non-recourse States, as predicted by the model. In terms of magni- tude, borrowers in non-recourse States are around 42% more likely to default on their mortgage.2 Column 4 shows that the probability of loan renegotiation is 28% higher in non-recourse States. This result is also in line with the model's predictions.

Moving on to pricing, Column 8 shows a puzzling result: the dierence in the interest rate between recourse and non-recourse loans is economically negligible at less than 1bp. In addition, the sign of this dierence is the opposite of what is predicted in the model. In a regression specication with no time or MSA xed eects, we nd that this dierence is not statistically signicant. Recalling that these results come from Fannie Mae's loan performance data, they provide evidence of an additional dimension of mispricing by GSEs. In addition to Hurst et al. (2016), who nd that GSEs do not correctly price regional risk, we show that such enterprises do not take into account ex-ante predictable non-recourse risk. In order to shed light on this issue, in the next section we take a step

2These results are qualitatively robust if we only use the cross-section of loans rather than the full panel. In the baseline, we opt to use a period by period approach to account for time spent in delinquency and possibility of cure. This also allows including running variables as controls, such as house price, in line with the model.

ECB Working Paper Series No 2519 / January 2021

26

back and use the HMDA dataset to evaluate loan prices at the loan application stage,

where data is available also for the private sector.

Table 3: Regression Results

Logit - odds ratios

OLS

(1)

(2)

(3)

(4)

(5)

(6)

VARIABLES

Default

Default

Renegotiation

Renegotiation

Interest Rate

Interest Rate

DNR

1.474***

1.416***

1.268***

1.282***

0.009**

-0.008***

(0.084)

(0.079)

(0.092)

(0.095)

(0.004)

(0.003)

Credit Score

0.982***

0.990***

-0.002***

(<.001)

(0.001)

(<.001)

Months to Maturity

1.004***

1.037***

0.003***

(0.001)

(0.001)

(<.001)

DTI

1.051***

1.030***

0.002***

(0.002)

(0.003)

(<.001)

Current Balance

1.000***

1.000***

(<.001)

(<.001)

Market Price

0.999***

0.999***

(<.001)

(<.001)

Observations

4,052,363

3,436,163

3,650,449

3,124,426

100,298

98,617

R-squared

0.859

0.904

Pseudo R2

0.149

0.250

0.053

0.396

MSA FE

YES

YES

YES

YES

YES

YES

Time FE

YES

YES

YES

YES

YES

YES

Heteroskedasticity robust standard errors in parentheses

*** p<0.01, ** p<0.05, * p<0.1

Notes: Columns 1-4 report Logit coecient estimates in odds ratios to facilitate the comparison and interpretation of the relative probability of default and modication between recourse and non-recourse States. Values above (below) unity indicate a positive (negative) relation between the independent variable and the likelihood of default or modication. The standard errors reported in parentheses for the Logit regressions are computed via Delta method to match the odds ratio coecients. Columns 5-6 report OLS estimates estimated using observations at origination only. Source: Fannie Mae Single Family Loan Database, Federal Housing Finance Agency and authors own calculations, 2004-2016.

4.2 Understanding loan pricing

In this section we focus on loan applications data in order to examine whether there are dierences in loan demand, loan origination, and loan sales that could explain the pricing puzzle outlined in the previous section.

ECB Working Paper Series No 2519 / January 2021

27

4.2.1 Loan origination and sale

Table 4 shows the mean values for some key variables in the HMDA Dataset, separated by recourse and non-recourse, together with the p-values for the two-sidedt-test of whether they are statistically dierent from each other.

Both origination rates and sales to third parties are higher in recourse States. The average income of the applicant is higher in non-recourse States, whereas the median income is equal across jurisdictions, indicating the presence of outliers. Loan amounts of all received applications, as well as those of accepted loans, are signicantly dierent in statistical terms, but are very similar in economic terms, diering by roughly $1,500. Importantly though, loan-to-income ratios of all applications as well as of originated loans are signicantly higher in recourse States. The loan-to-income ratio is a measure of the burden that the loan repayment poses on the borrowers' payment capacity, hence higher loan-to-income is associated with a higher risk of default. The fact that recourse States display higher loan-to-income ratios of granted loans may indicate that lenders are more willing to take on risk in recourse States because they have a higher recovery ratio given that they can seize the borrowers' personal assets in the event of default.

ECB Working Paper Series No 2519 / January 2021

28

Table 4: HMDA

Non-recourse

Recourse

p-value

All Applications

Annual income of applicant ($)

84,723

80,846

<.001

Median annual income ($)

67,000

67,000

.

Loan amount ($)

151,716

153,358

<.001

Loan-to-income

2.055

2.155

<.001

Originated Loans

Annual income of applicant ($)

89,592

84,430

<.001

Median income ($)

72,000

71,000

.

Loan amount ($)

157,237

155,573

<.001

Loan-to-income

2.012

2.101

<.001

Loan acceptance rate (%)

54.04

55.27

<.001

Sold to 3rd party (%)

67.39

68.83

<.001

N. of observations

1,370,430

2,013,317 .

Notes: Income and loan amounts are in US dollars. Loan-to-income is the ratio of the loan amount over the annual income of the applicant. The acceptance rate is the percentage of loan applications that were granted. Loans sold to 3rd parties reect the percentage of granted loans that were sold to a 3rd party in the natural year in which the loan was originated. Source: Home Mortgage Disclosure Act Database and authors own calculations, 2004-2016.

First, we focus on the characteristics of loan applications, as well as on the lenders' willingness to lend given the applications it receives on either side of the border.

The distribution of income of applications is depicted in Figure 4. There are no signicant dierences in the distribution of income of applicants on either side of the border. We can therefore conclude that any dierences in the probability to originate a loan are due to dierences in limited liability.

Figure 5 illustrates the dierences in reasons for denial. The most common reason for denial is the credit history of the borrower in both types of States. The second most frequent reason in recourse States is the debt-to-income ratio, followed by the value of the collateral (the real estate property). Notably, this order is reversed in non-recourse States, indicating that collateral value is more important to lenders in States with limited liability. This is intuitive since limited liability implies that the lender may be limited in how much they can recover from the borrower in case of default, making the value of

ECB Working Paper Series No 2519 / January 2021

29

Figure 4: Income distributions

Notes: Distributions of yearly income is US Dollars at the loan application stage

split by recourse and non-recourse States. Source: Home Mortgage Disclosure Act Database and authors own calculations, 2004-2016.

ECB Working Paper Series No 2519 / January 2021

30

Figure 5: Reasons for loan denial

Notes: The height of the bars in the histograms indicate the frequency of different reasons for loan denial split by recourse and non-recourse States. Source: Home Mortgage Disclosure Act Database and authors own calculations, 2004- 2016.

collateral an important source of compensation for this risk.

Next, we are also interested in the originate-to-distribute behaviour of banks. Leading up to the Financial Crisis in 2007, and ever since, it has become increasingly evident that the business model of many lenders is to originate mortgages and sell them to third parties, thereby eliminating credit risk from their balance sheets. Figure 6 contains information about the proportion of loans that were sold to a third party in the year of its origination and the identity of the purchaser.

It can be seen from the Figure that lenders sell just under 70% of their loans to third parties. The most common purchasers are State Agencies, Fannie Mae and Freddie Mac. Banks sell slightly more non-recourse loans than recourse loans.

ECB Working Paper Series No 2519 / January 2021

31

Figure 6: Loan sales

Notes: The height of the bars in the histograms indicate the percentage of loans kept on the issuer's balance sheet or sold to a range of public and private purchasers split by recourse and non-recourse States. Source: Home Mortgage Disclosure Act Database, 2004-2016.

We would like to examine how recourse aects the willingness of banks to grant a loan conditional on application characteristics. Following Dell'Ariccia et al. (2012), we use the loan-to-income ratio at origination as a proxy for the ex-ante risk of a loan.3 A higher loan-to-income is associated with a higher risk of default since the loan obligation weighs heavier on the borrower's ability to pay. We use a Logit model of the following form:

LO = 1 + 2DNR + 3LtIi + 4DNRLtIi + i

(14)

where LO are the log odds of a loan being originated; DNR is a dummy variable that

3The only further borrower characteristics included in HMDA are self-reported ethnicity, race and gender. Results are robust to including this set of controls.

ECB Working Paper Series No 2519 / January 2021

32

takes value 1 if the property is located in a non-recourse State and 0 otherwise, LtIi is the loan-to-income ratio of application i. 4 is then the regression coecient for the interaction term between the non-recourse dummy and the loan-to-income ratio.

We also run a Logit model of the same form to assess the dierence in the probability of selling a loan to a third party:

LS = 1 + 2DNR + 3LtIi + 4DNRLtIi + i;t

(15)

where LS are the log odds of a loan being sold.

Table 5 shows the results of these regressions. The interpretation of interaction terms in Logit regression needs careful consideration. First, it is worth noting that the regression results are expressed in terms of log odds. While Logit models are linear in log odds, they are not linear in other metrics such as probabilities. We want to be able to interpret the results of these regressions in terms of the dierence in the probability of originating a loan between recourse and non-recourse,conditional on the ex-ante risk of the loan as proxied by the loan-to-income ratio. This probability dierence will therefore depend on the dierent values of the model variables. Furthermore, the interaction term is composed by a categorical variable and a continuous variable, so in order to interpret the results, it will be necessary to evaluate the coecient at dierent levels of loan-to-income.4

4While we follow Dell'Ariccia et al. (2012) in the use of loan-to-income as a key variable to measure the riskiness of a mortgage, results are comparable if we use income instead.

ECB Working Paper Series No 2519 / January 2021

33

Table 5: Loan Origination and Sale

(1)

(2)

(3)

(4)

VARIABLES

Origination

Origination

Loan Sale

Loan Sale

DNR

-0.158***

-0.106***

-0.261***

0.111***

(0.004)

(0.008)

(0.005)

(0.011)

LtI

-0.051***

-0.042***

0.310***

0.394***

(0.002)

(0.002)

(0.002)

(0.003)

DNRLtI

-0.022***

-0.179***

(0.003)

(0.005)

Constant

0.677***

0.653***

0.584***

0.408***

(0.004)

(0.005)

(0.006)

(0.008)

Observations 1,286,996 1,286,996 796,090 796,090

Heteroskedasticity robust standard errors in parentheses

*** p<0.01, ** p<0.05, * p<0.1

Notes: This table shows Logit regression results for loan origination and loan sale. The coecients are expressed in log odds. The dependent variable in Columns 1-2 are the log odds of a loan being originated, and in Columns 3-4 the log odds of an originated loan being sold. Dependent variables include a dummy variable (DNR) that denotes non-recourse States, the Loan-to-income ratio (LtI) as a proxy for loan riskiness, and the interaction between the two. Source: Home Mortgage Disclosure Act Database and authors own calculations, 2004-2016.

We therefore use the margins of responses to retrieve the estimated probabilities of origination and sale for recourse and non-recourse. We then plot the dierences in estimated probabilities for dierent values of loan-to-income, together with their 95% condence intervals. Figure 7 presents the results.

As can be seen, banks are less likely to originate loans in non-recourse States, and this probability is decreasing in the loan-to-income ratio. This is an intuitive result since non- recourse loans can be considered 'riskier' because of limited liability. For a given level of LtI risk, banks would rather lend in a State where they can seize the borrower's assets in the event of default. At the same time, banks are less likely to sell non-recourse loans to third parties, and this probability is also decreasing in loan-to-income.

ECB Working Paper Series No 2519 / January 2021

34

Figure 7: Dierences in probability of Origination and Sale

Notes: The solid line plots the dierence in the probability of origination and sale between recourse and non-recourse States for dierent levels of loan-to- income ratios (a proxy of the riskiness of the loan). The dashed lines trace the 95% condence intervals. Source: Home Mortgage Disclosure Act Database and authors own calculations, 2004-2016.

4.2.2 Interest rate on sold loans

One of the striking results from Table 3 is that for loans bought by Fannie Mae, the interest rate at origination does not dier between recourse and non-recourse loans. Given that non-recourse loans are expected to have a lower recovery rate in the event of default, one could expect the interest rate for these loans to be higher. We ask whether the fact that the interest rate at origination does not dier across jurisdictions for loans that were sold to Fannie Mae is due to the fact that banks anticipated they would sell this loans to a third party and therefore did not have an incentive to price in their risk. To this end, we use the HMDA loan application database to test whether loans that were not sold to a third party were priced dierently, conditional on observables.

ECB Working Paper Series No 2519 / January 2021

35

While the loan application data does not include the interest rate of each loan, banks report the spread between the rate charged for a given loan and the average interest rate that a loan with similar characteristics would have in the market. Banks must report the spread (di erence) between the annual percentage rate (APR) and the applicable average prime o er rate if the spread is equal to or greater than 1.5 percentage points for rst-lien loans. Due to this, there is a selection issue on the spread variable: we do not observe the spread if it is lower than the reporting threshold. In order to overcome this issue, some papers in the literature, for instance Pennington-Cross and Ho (2008), have applied the Heckman two-stage procedure for selection correction to this dataset. Hence, we run the following Probit regression:

Yi = Xi + ui

(16)

where Yi takes value 1 if the spread of loan application i is observed (i.e. if the spread is greater than 1.5 percentage points), and Xi is a set of variables that inuence the probability of the spread being above the reporting threshold. We use all available borrower information in Xi, which includes income and dummy variables for self-reported

race and gender.

^

^

^

(X)

We then use to compute the inverse Mills ratio, (X) =

, and it to di erent

^

(X)

second stage regressions in order to answer di erent questions. First, we examine the di erence in the spread between recourse and non-recourse States using the following regression:

^

(17)

spreadi = 0 + 1DNR + (X) + i

where DNR takes value 1 for non-recourse loans and 0 otherwise. Then, we ask whether the spread is higher for loans that are sold to third parties, and whether this di ers across jurisdictions. The regression reads:

ECB Working Paper Series No 2519 / January 2021

36

^

(18)

spreadi = 0 + 1DNR + 2DSold + 3DNRDSold + (X) + i

where DSold takes value 1 for loans that were sold to third parties and 0 otherwise and DNRDSold is an interaction term of both dummy variables.

Hurst et al. (2016) show that public agencies such as Fannie Mae and Freddie Mac are less ecient at pricing mortgage loan risk than the private market. They argue that this price dierence leads to cross subsidisation from low risk mortgages to high risk mortgages. We explore whether this issue extends to the dierence in risk between recourse and non-recourse loans in the following way:

^

(19)

spreadi = 0 + 1DNR + 2DP rivate + 3DNRDP rivate + (X) + i

where DP rivate takes value 1 for loans that were sold to private buyers (securitisation agencies, commercial banks, insurance companies, funds...) and 0 for loans that were sold to public buyers (Fannie Mae, Freddie Mac, Ginnie Mae and Farmer Mac).

The results of these regressions are laid out in Table 6. Regression 17 is shown in Column 1. The loan spread is signicantly lower in non-recourse States which is a surprising result. We are interested, however, in whether there is a signicant dierence in loan pricing for loans that were sold to third parties, and among those, whether there is a dierence between private and public buyers. Column 2 presents the results of Regression

18. The constant term implies that the average spread of a recourse loan that was kept by the bank is around 6:7%. The coecient of DNR captures the dierence in the interest rate between non-recourse and recourse for unsold loans. The interest rate on unsold

loans is 24bp lower for non-recourse loans. The coecient for DSold equals the dierence between sold and kept loans in recourse States. It implies that, among recourse loans, the spread is around 5bp lower for those that were sold. The coecient for the interaction term DNRDSold is equivalent to a dierence-in-dierences estimator. It represents the

ECB Working Paper Series No 2519 / January 2021

37

dierence in the spread between recourse and non-recourse loans for loans that were sold. The fact that it is positive and statistically signicant indicates that in the market for loan sales the spread is higher for non-recourse mortgages. This result is intuitive, since non-recourse implies a higher rate of default as predicted by the theoretical model, and shown empirically in the previous section. We note that there may be an endogeneity issue in interacting DNR and DSold, as we have shown before that non-recourse loans are less likely to be sold to third parties than their recourse counterparts.

This phenomenon is further investigated in Column 3, where the pool of sold loans is split between private and public buyers, as outlined in regression 19. The coecient for DP rivate indicates the dierence between loans sold to private and public agents in recourse States. The estimate of this dierence is almost 200bp, which is an order of magnitude higher than the DSold coecient in Column 1. This implies that most of the variation in the spread of sold loans is driven by pricing behaviour of private investors.

The coecient for the interaction term DNRDP rivate is also positive and statistically signicant. It means that for non-recourse loans, private purchasers demand a higher spread than public agencies. This suggests that private markets price in the higher risk associated with non-recourse loans (or limited liability) to a greater extent than their public counterparts. We conclude from this analysis that banks do charge signicantly higher interest rates on non-recourse loans when selling the loan to a private third party, while loans bought by Fannie Mae seem to have the same interest rate at origination, as was shown in Table 2. These results are in contrast with Hurst et al. (2016), who nd that interest rates do not vary across recourse and non-recourse States for both private and public loans.

ECB Working Paper Series No 2519 / January 2021

38

Table 6: Heckman Regression Results

(1)

(2)

(3)

EQUATION

VARIABLES

spread

spread

spread

Second Stage

DNR

-0.085***

-0.242***

-0.006

(0.008)

(0.013)

(0.025)

DSold

-0.052***

(0.011)

DNRDSold

0.266***

(0.017)

DP rivate

1.978***

(0.021)

DNRDP rivate

0.222***

(0.032)

Constant

6.722***

6.731***

4.913***

(0.047)

(0.048)

(0.123)

First Stage

Income

-0.002***

-0.002***

-0.002***

(0.000)

(0.000)

(0.000)

Female

0.051***

0.051***

0.040***

(0.002)

(0.002)

(0.004)

Native

-0.014

-0.014

-0.082***

(0.015)

(0.015)

(0.030)

Asian

-0.149***

-0.149***

-0.046***

(0.008)

(0.008)

(0.014)

Black

0.339***

0.339***

0.314***

(0.003)

(0.003)

(0.005)

Hawaiian

0.051***

0.051***

0.049

(0.017)

(0.017)

(0.031)

Constant

-1.363***

-1.363***

-2.112***

(0.002)

(0.002)

(0.004)

Observations 3,072,488 3,072,488 2,897,723

Standard errors in parentheses

*** p<0.01, ** p<0.05, * p<0.1

Notes: This table shows the rst and second stage of the two-step Heckman procedure for selection correction. The rst stage is a Probit regression where the probability of being selected depends on borrower observables. We include as selection variables the borrower's income, gender, and race. The inverse Mills ratio is computed from the rst stage and is used in the second stage regression as an independent variable together with other explanatory variables. DNR is a dummy variable that takes value 1 for non-recourse States and 0 for recourse States, DSold is a dummy variable that takes value 1 for loans that were sold an 0 for loans that were kept by the bank, DP rivate is a dummy variable for loans that were sold to a private entity and 0 for loans that were sold to a public enterprise (GSE). Standard errors are corrected to account for the two-step procedure. Source: Home Mortgage Disclosure Act Database and authors own calculations, 2004-2016.

ECB Working Paper Series No 2519 / January 2021

39

  • Conclusion

The rise of household indebtedness before the Financial Crisis combined with high default rates was a root cause of the Great Recession and underlined the role of consumer nance for the macroeconomy. Mortgage debt in particular, constitutes two-thirds of US household total debt, and it currently follows an increasing trend.

While there are several factors that determine the rate of mortgage default, such as adverse economic shocks that leave households unable to honour their debt, default may also be a voluntary choice, commonly referred to as strategic default. One particular aspect the household may consider before choosing to default is whether there is limited liability in place. Under limited liability, the lender is not allowed to seize the household's assets after default. On the contrary, under lender recourse, the lender is allowed to claw back the borrower's assets after default.

While the literature has analysed the consequences of limited liability, such as default rates, loan renegotiation or forbearance, and interest rates in isolation, we embody all these features in our analysis as equilibrium outcomes of the strategic interaction between borrowers and lenders.

We use a model of default and renegotiation to highlight the mechanisms at hand, and we test them empirically by exploiting the dierence in legislation across US States. We do this by comparing loans for houses situated in Metropolitan Statistical Areas that are crossed by a State border, where one State enforces lender recourse and the other does not. Given than MSAs are dened by the US Census Bureau as a core area containing a substantial population nucleus, together with adjacent communities having a high degree of economic and social integration with that core', we argue that borrowers on either side of the border are exposed to the same economic shocks, and the dierence in their

ECB Working Paper Series No 2519 / January 2021

40

behaviour towards their mortgage loans can be thought to stem exclusively from the presence or absence or limited liability.

In the model, both house prices and the income of the borrower are stochastic. In some states of the world, the household has enough income to pay their mortgage, whereas in other states of the world it does not. Likewise, in some states of the world, the house value is higher than the mortgage amount, i.e. the household has positive equity, whereas in other states of the world the house value is lower, i.e. the mortgage is underwater. Households who can a ord to meet their payments, but whose mortgage is underwater, may nd it optimal to default, in particular on instances where it is unlikely that they will be liable with their personal assets after default. Lenders who know this may nd it optimal to o er these households a renegotiated mortgage price in order to prevent them from walking away from their obligations. At the same time, the price of these loans will reect these mechanisms. Loan rates are expected to be higher under limited liability, because of the higher ex-ante predictable default and renegotiation risk, and the lower recovery rate for the lender after default.

These predictions are con rmed by the data. In fact, non-recourse loans are around 42% more likely to default, and 28% more likely to receive a renegotiation o er. However, while the model predicts that loan rates should be higher for non-recourse loans (as they have a higher expected default rate), loan performance data from Fannie Mae does not con rm this. This lack of price di erentiation has been noted in the literature, for instance by Hurst et al. (2016). They note that Government-Sponsored Enterprises (GSEs) fail to appropriately price in regional di erences in ex-ante predictable default risk. In this paper, regional risk is expected to be the same within each MSA, as they are by de nition integrated economic areas. However, we still nd a lack of price di erentiation on the side of GSEs, which fail to account for the risk of default and renegotiation brought about by the di erence in legislation. We test this by using additional data from the Home

ECB Working Paper Series No 2519 / January 2021

41

Mortgage Disclosure Act (HMDA) in order to compare the interest rates on loans that were sold to private investors vs GSEs, for recourse and non-recourse States. We nd that the dierence in default risk implied by dierent recourse laws is indeed priced into loans that are securitised by private investors. Overall, rates on non-recourse loans sold to private investors are around 22bp higher than their recourse counterparts.

These results overall speak to the distortions imposed by the dierences in limited liability across States, together with the heterogeneity of public and private market par- ticipants. Given the size of the market and the importance of mortgages in households' balance sheets, our ndings have important macroeconomic implications. Further theoretical research should ll the gap in how these mechanisms interact in general equilibrium.

ECB Working Paper Series No 2519 / January 2021

42

Appendix A: Equilibria under dierent relative values of thresholds (1) and (2)

Figure 8a shows the same graphic representation for the case when (1) < (2). In this case, for values of weakly greater or smaller than the threshold, the above logic still holds. However, for values between (1) and (2), the household would nd it optimal not to default, so the lender would not renegotiate. For = (1), the borrower would mix between defaulting and repaying. If it defaults, then the lender would mix between renegotiating or not. The same logic holds when = (1) = (2), which is represented in gure 8b.

(a) (1) < (2)

(b) (1) = (2)

Figure 8: Equilibria for dierent relative values of (1) and (2)

ECB Working Paper Series No 2519 / January 2021

43

References

Atkeson, A. (1991). International lending with moral hazard and risk of repudiation. Econometrica, pages 1069{1089.

Bester, H. (1994). The role of collateral in a model of debt renegotiation. Journal of money, credit and banking, 26(1):72{86.

Campbell, J. Y. (2012). Mortgage market design. Review of Finance, 17(1):1{33.

Chan, S., Haughwout, A., Hayashi, A., and Van der Klaauw, W. (2016). Determinants of mortgage default and consumer credit use: the eects of foreclosure laws and foreclosure delays. Journal of Money, Credit and Banking, 48(2-3):393{413.

Collins, J. M., Lam, K., and Herbert, C. E. (2011). State mortgage foreclosure policies and lender interventions: Impacts on borrower behavior in default. Journal of Policy Analysis and Management, 30(2):216{232.

Curtis, Q. (2014). State foreclosure laws and mortgage origination in the subprime. The Journal of Real Estate Finance and Economics, 49(3):303{328.

Dagher, J. and Sun, Y. (2016). Borrower protection and the supply of credit: Evidence from foreclosure laws. Journal of Financial Economics, 121(1):195{209.

Dell'Ariccia, G., Igan, D., and Laeven, L. (2012). Credit Booms and Lending Standards: Evidence from the Subprime Mortgage Market. Journal of Money, Credit and Banking, 44:367{384.

Gerardi, K., Lambie-Hanson, L., and Willen, P. S. (2013). Do borrower rights improve borrower outcomes? evidence from the foreclosure process. Journal of Urban Economics, 73(1):1{17.

ECB Working Paper Series No 2519 / January 2021

44

Ghent, A. C. and Kudlyak, M. (2011). Recourse and residential mortgage default: evidence from us states. Review of Financial Studies, 24(9):3139{3186.

Gianinazzi, V., Pelizzon, L., and Plazzi, A. (2019). Residential mortgage defaults and positive equity: Lessons from europe. Working Paper.

Grossman, H. I. and Van Huyck, J. B. (1988). Sovereign debt as a contingent claim: Excusable default, repudiation, and reputation. American Economic Review, 78(5):1088{ 1097.

Guren, A. M., Krishnamurthy, A., and McQuade, T. J. (2018). Mortgage design in an equilibrium model of the housing market. NBER.

Hart, O. and Moore, J. (1998). Default and renegotiation: A dynamic model of debt. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 113(1):1{41.

Hurst, E., Keys, B. J., Seru, A., and Vavra, J. (2016). Regional redistribution through the us mortgage market. American Economic Review, 106(10):2982{3028.

Jeske, K. (2006). Private international debt with risk of repudiation. Journal of political Economy, 114(3):576{593.

Kaplan, G., Mitman, K., and Violante, G. L. (2017). The housing boom and bust: Model meets evidence. NBER.

Li, W. and Oswald, F. (2017). Recourse and residential mortgages: The case of nevada. Journal of Urban Economics, 101:1{13.

Meador, M. (1982). The eects of mortgage laws on home mortgage rates. Journal of Economics and Business, 34(2):143{148.

Mian, A., Su, A., and Trebbi, F. (2015). Foreclosures, house prices, and the real economy. The Journal of Finance, 70(6):2587{2634.

ECB Working Paper Series No 2519 / January 2021

45

Pence, K. M. (2006). Foreclosing on opportunity: State laws and mortgage credit. Review of Economics and Statistics, 88(1):177{182.

Pennington-Cross, A. and Ho, G. (2008). Predatory lending laws and the cost of credit. Real Estate Economics, 36(2):175{211.

ECB Working Paper Series No 2519 / January 2021

46

Acknowledgements

We are grateful to Chris Brooks, Michael Clements, Russell Cooper, Juan José Dolado, Matteo Escudé, Nadia Kappou, David K. Levine, Ramón Marimón, Steven Ongena, Giorgio Primiceri, Rafael Repullo, Paul Voß, and various seminar participants at EUI, ICMA Centre at the Henley Business School, and at the 2019 EDP Jamboree in UCLouvain for useful comments and suggestions. We also thank the Editorial Board of the ECB Working Paper Series, as well as an anonymous referee. The views expressed are our own and do not necessarily reflect those of the European Central Bank or the Eurosystem.

Mirco Balatti

European Central Bank, Frankfurt am Main, Germany; ICMA Centre, Henley Business School, Reading, United Kingdom; email: mirco.balatti@ecb.europa.eu

Carolina López-Quiles

European Central Bank, Frankfurt am Main, Germany; European University Institute, Florence, Italy; email: carolina.lopez-quiles_centeno@ecb.europa.eu

© European Central Bank, 2021

Postal address 60640 Frankfurt am Main, Germany

Telephone +49 69 1344 0

Website www.ecb.europa.eu

All rights reserved. Any reproduction, publication and reprint in the form of a different publication, whether printed or produced electronically, in whole or in part, is permitted only with the explicit written authorisation of the ECB or the authors.

This paper can be downloaded without charge from www.ecb.europa.eu, from the Social Science Research Network electronic library or from RePEc: Research Papers in Economics. Information on all of the papers published in the ECB Working Paper Series can be found on the ECB's website.

PDF

ISBN 978-92-899-4519-6

ISSN 1725-2806

doi:10.2866/502561

QB-AR-21-010-EN-N

This is an excerpt of the original content. To continue reading it, access the original document here.

Attachments

  • Original document
  • Permalink

Disclaimer

ECB - European Central Bank published this content on 29 January 2021 and is solely responsible for the information contained therein. Distributed by Public, unedited and unaltered, on 08 February 2021 15:02:00 UTC.